Commission Staff Working Doucment: Impact Assessment Accompanying the documents Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, the European Economic and Social Committee and he Committee of the Regions a Clean Air Programme for Europe, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the limitation of emissions of certain pollutants into the air from medium combustion plants, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the reduction of national emissions of certain atmospheric pollutants and amending Directive 2003/35/EC, Proposal for a Council Decision on the acceptance of the Amendment to the 1999 Protocol to the 1979 Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution to Abate Acidification, Eutrophication and Ground-level Ozone - Hoofdinhoud
Documentdatum | 23-12-2013 |
---|---|
Publicatiedatum | 26-12-2013 |
Kenmerk | 18167/13 ADD 5 |
Van | Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director |
Externe link | origineel bericht |
Originele document in PDF |
COUNCIL OF Brussels, 23 December 2013 THE EUROPEAN UNION (OR. en)
18167/13 ADD 5
ENV 1235 ENER 600 IND 388 TRANS 693 ENT 356 SAN 555 PARLNAT 325 CODEC 3086
COVER NOTE
From: Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director
date of receipt: 20 December 2013
To: Mr Uwe CORSEPIUS, Secretary-General of the Council of the European
Union
No. Cion doc.: SWD(2013) 531 final PART 4/4
Subject: Commission Staff Working Doucment: Impact Assessment Accompanying the documents Communication from the Commission to the Council, the
European Parliament, the European Economic and Social Committee and he
Committee of the Regions a Clean Air Programme for Europe, Proposal for
a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the limitation
of emissions of certain pollutants into the air from medium combustion
plants, Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the
Council on the reduction of national emissions of certain atmospheric
pollutants and amending Directive 2003/35/EC i, Proposal for a Council
Decision on the acceptance of the Amendment to the 1999 Protocol to the
1979 Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution to Abate
Acidification, Eutrophication and Ground-level Ozone
Delegations will find attached document SWD(2013) 531 final PART 4/4.
Encl.: SWD(2013) 531 final PART 4/4
18167/13 ADD 5 CM/ach
DG E 1A EN
EUROPEAN COMMISSION
Brussels, 18.12.2013 SWD(2013) 531 final
PART 4/4
COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT
IMPACT ASSESSMENT
Accompanying the document
Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, the European Economic and Social Committee and he Committee of the Regions a Clean
Air Programme for Europe
Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the limitation
of emissions of certain pollutants into the air from medium combustion plants
Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the reduction
of national emissions of certain atmospheric pollutants and amending Directive
2003/35/EC
Proposal for a Council Decision on the acceptance of the Amendment to the 1999 Protocol to the 1979 Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution to Abate
Acidification, Eutrophication and Ground-level Ozone
{COM(2013) 918 final i} {SWD(2013) 532 final} {COM(2013) 917 final i} {COM(2013) 918 final i} {COM(2013) 919 final i} {COM(2013) 920 final i}
EN EN
A PPENDIX 7.4 E MISSION REDUCTIONS REQUIRED OF THE M EMBER S TATES IN 2025 AND
2030 TO ACHIEVE THE IMPACT REDUCTION OBJECTIVES OF THE CENTRAL
CASE O PTION 6C*
2025 central case; emission ceilings in Kilotons; % reduction vs 2005
Country
SO2 % red NOx % red NH3 % red VOC % red PM2,5 % red
Austria 12 -52% 71 -69% 50 -20% 90 -47% 11 -54%
Belgium 46 -67% 123 -58% 62 -16% 88 -44% 15 -46%
Bulgaria 81 -91% 63 -62% 58 -11% 55 -61% 14 -60%
Croatia 9 -86% 27 -64% 20 -31% 38 -52% 5 -65%
Cyprus 1 -97% 7 -68% 5 -23% 4 -53% 1 -73%
Czech Rep. 65 -68% 114 -61% 52 -35% 113 -55% 23 -47%
Denmark 9 -56% 63 -65% 44 -40% 54 -59% 11 -62%
Estonia 20 -70% 18 -55% 9 -23% 26 -31% 10 -48%
Finland 63 -30% 110 -45% 27 -20% 95 -45% 18 -37%
France 103 -77% 453 -66% 463 -31% 571 -49% 154 -43%
Germany 295 -46% 517 -63% 318 -46% 715 -42% 73 -41%
Greece 52 -90% 130 -68% 41 -28% 92 -68% 16 -71%
Hungary 17 -86% 53 -66% 48 -38% 63 -57% 11 -61%
Ireland 13 -81% 54 -64% 89 -14% 43 -33% 9 -32%
Italy 93 -76% 447 -66% 298 -29% 566 -54% 85 -42%
Latvia 3 -47% 22 -39% 13 -1% 30 -57% 9 -52%
Lithuania 11 -74% 29 -54% 40 -10% 34 -59% 7 -55%
Luxembourg 1 -44% 13 -73% 5 -25% 5 -58% 2 -47%
Malta 0,2 -98% 1 -86% 1 -26% 3 -32% 0,2 -79%
Netherlands 30 -57% 134 -65% 111 -24% 135 -34% 15 -38%
Poland 332 -74% 398 -50% 243 -29% 286 -53% 154 -31%
Portugal 23 -79% 76 -72% 55 -22% 118 -48% 19 -69%
Romania 55 -92% 111 -64% 115 -29% 171 -63% 44 -61%
Slovakia 20 -78% 42 -55% 17 -41% 45 -41% 12 -62%
Slovenia 5 -88% 17 -66% 14 -26% 15 -62% 2 -73%
Spain 152 -89% 418 -72% 256 -30% 488 -48% 61 -61%
Sweden 30 -22% 82 -62% 43 -20% 136 -35% 21 -33%
Un. Kingdom 153 -82% 450 -70% 240 -22% 550 -50% 46 -47%
EU-28 1697 -79% 4043 -65% 2740 -30% 4630 -50% 848 -48%
230
2030 central case; emission ceilings in Kilotons; % reduction vs 2005
Country
SO2 % red NOx % red NH3 % red VOC % red PM2,5 % red
Austria 11 -54% 60 -74% 51 -20% 89 -48% 11 -55%
Belgium 44 -68% 112 -62% 62 -16% 89 -44% 15 -46%
Bulgaria 53 -94% 55 -67% 58 -11% 51 -63% 12 -64%
Croatia 9 -87% 25 -68% 21 -30% 36 -55% 5 -67%
Cyprus 1 -97% 6 -71% 5 -21% 4 -54% 1 -73%
Czech Rep. 59 -72% 99 -67% 51 -36% 111 -56% 22 -49%
Denmark 9 -58% 55 -70% 43 -41% 53 -59% 10 -64%
Estonia 19 -71% 16 -61% 9 -21% 24 -37% 10 -52%
Finland 63 -30% 99 -51% 28 -18% 91 -47% 17 -41%
France 98 -78% 395 -71% 458 -32% 559 -50% 141 -48%
Germany 258 -53% 435 -69% 312 -47% 705 -43% 70 -43%
Greece 38 -92% 110 -73% 41 -28% 89 -69% 17 -72%
Hungary 16 -88% 46 -70% 49 -37% 61 -58% 11 -63%
Ireland 11 -84% 35 -77% 89 -14% 42 -33% 9 -35%
Italy 92 -76% 390 -70% 301 -29% 554 -55% 81 -45%
Latvia 3 -47% 19 -47% 13 2% 30 -56% 8 -54%
Lithuania 12 -72% 26 -58% 44 -1% 33 -60% 6 -57%
Luxembourg 1 -44% 10 -79% 5 -25% 5 -59% 2 -48%
Malta 0,2 -98% 1 -89% 1 -27% 3 -31% 0,1 -80%
Netherlands 28 -59% 121 -68% 109 -25% 133 -35% 15 -39%
Poland 278 -78% 338 -58% 244 -29% 280 -54% 140 -38%
Portugal 23 -79% 65 -76% 56 -20% 119 -48% 19 -69%
Romania 51 -93% 100 -68% 113 -30% 165 -64% 41 -64%
Slovakia 20 -79% 39 -59% 17 -41% 45 -41% 12 -62%
Slovenia 5 -89% 14 -72% 14 -26% 15 -63% 2 -74%
Spain 151 -89% 354 -77% 255 -30% 488 -48% 62 -60%
Sweden 32 -16% 75 -65% 43 -19% 131 -38% 20 -34%
Un. Kingdom 128 -85% 391 -74% 244 -21% 545 -50% 46 -48%
EU-28 1513 -81% 3490 -70% 2734 -30% 4551 -51% 806 -51%
231 A PPENDIX 7.5 E MISSION REDUCTIONS COST EFFECTIVE IN INDIVIDUAL SECTORS IN 2025
AND 2030 TO ACHIEVE THE IMPACT REDUCTION OBJECTIVES OF THE
CENTRAL CASE O PTION 6C*
232
2025 central case; emissions in Kilotons; % reduction vs Baseline (Option 1)
233
Sector
SO2 % red NOx % red NH3 % red VOC % red PM2,5 % red
Power generation 671 -19% 860 -19% 17 -30% 132 -23% 30 -50%
Domestic combustion 255 -36% 504 0% 20 0% 390 -52% 359 -31%
Industrial combustion 388 -35% 616 -31% 5 -14% 77 0% 43 -40%
Industrial Processes 347 -39% 167 -2% 60 -19% 773 -5% 147 -26%
Fuel extraction 0 0 0 290 -5% 7 0%
Solvent use 0 0 0 2328 -10% 0
Road transport 5 0% 1210 0% 48 0% 293 0% 104 0%
Non-road machinery 31 -15% 684 -9% 1 -45% 271 -13% 37 -8%
Waste 1 -76% 1 -82% 173 0% 75 -13% 64 -29%
Agriculture 0 -100% 1 -96% 2416 -27% 0 -100% 58 -66%
total 1697 -31% 4043 -12% 2740 -25% 4630 -17% 848 -33%
2030 central case; emissions in Kilotons; % reduction vs Baseline (Option 1)
Sector
SO2 % red NOx % red NH3 % red VOC % red PM2,5 % red
Power generation 520 -18% 720 -20% 15 -33% 117 -28% 25 -53%
Domestic combustion 217,9 -35% 470 0% 19 0% 362 -51% 323,7 -30%
Industrial combustion 390 -36% 633 -32% 5 -15% 85 0% 45 -40%
Industrial Processes 348 -40% 167 -2% 60 -20% 778 -5% 149 -26%
Fuel extraction 0 0 0 275 -5% 6 0%
Solvent use 0 0 0 2342 -10% 0
Road transport 5 0% 887 0% 46 0% 257 0% 102 0%
Non-road machinery 31 -15% 611 -8% 1 -45% 262 -7% 33 -5%
Waste 1 -77% 1 -84% 173 0% 74 -12% 64 -29%
Agriculture 0 -100% 1 -96% 2415 -27% 0 -100% 58 -66%
total 1513 -32% 3490 -14% 2734 -25% 4551 -17% 806 -33%
234 A PPENDIX 7.6 I MPACT REDUCTIONS IN THE M EMBER S TATES IN 2025 AND 2030 IN THE
CENTRAL CASE O PTION 6C* COMPARED TO O PTION 1
2025 central case; impact % reduction vs baseline (Option 1)
PM human Premature Forest area Ecosystem area
Country mortality, years of life lost, deaths due to exceeding exceeding
million ozone acidification limits
eutrophication limits
% red % red % red % red
Austria 2,56 -20% 287 -7% 0 8338 -52%
Belgium 4,55 -17% 247 -6% 19 -36% 1 -95%
Bulgaria 2,97 -18% 508 -5% 0 11576 -19%
Croatia 1,37 -19% 199 -9% 51 -83% 21830 -11%
Cyprus 0,52 -2% 41 -2% 0 2528 0%
Czech Rep. 4,21 -21% 343 -7% 377 -59% 1183 -31%
Denmark 1,41 -16% 120 -5% 10 -72% 4144 -2%
Estonia 0,39 -8% 27 -4% 0 3197 -29%
Finland 1,19 -7% 68 -4% 0 5476 -31%
France 21,03 -15% 1596 -5% 403 -87% 87546 -28%
Germany 28,17 -18% 2525 -6% 865 -80% 33851 -33%
Greece 5,08 -17% 604 -5% 73 -63% 54080 -2%
Hungary 3,95 -22% 486 -8% 432 -60% 15898 -17%
Ireland 0,77 -10% 48 -2% 0 -91% 409 -33%
Italy 25,18 -23% 3369 -6% 2 -96% 38408 -32%
Latvia 0,72 -14% 62 -5% 587 -45% 22755 -15%
Lithuania 1,16 -15% 98 -4% 5380 -7% 18142 -4%
Luxembourg 0,19 -17% 11 -8% 3 -97% 1084 -3%
Malta 0,12 -7% 18 -5% 0 0
Netherlands 6,16 -15% 316 -5% 3376 -12% 3530 -9%
Poland 21,88 -23% 1079 -7% 7435 -61% 45381 -24%
Portugal 2,73 -26% 423 -5% 132 -30% 30385 -7%
Romania 8,92 -23% 983 -7% 0 -100% 84115 -5%
Slovakia 2,09 -24% 185 -8% 44 -92% 18489 -6%
Slovenia 0,62 -27% 76 -10% 0 -100% 500 -77%
Spain 12,79 -21% 1506 -4% 4 -92% 191606 -5%
Sweden 1,68 -8% 164 -4% 4205 -20% 32800 -27%
Un. Kingdom 15,18 -25% 1121 -5% 394 -59% 1743 -57%
EU-28 177,58 -20% 16509 -6% 23791 -50% 738994 -17%
235
2030 central case; impact % reduction vs baseline (Option 1)
PM human Forest area Ecosystem area Country mortality, years
Premature
of life lost, deaths due to exceeding
exceeding
million ozone acidification limits
eutrophication limits
% red % red % red % red
Austria 2,45 -20% 274 -7% 0 7121 -56%
Belgium 4,40 -17% 241 -5% 11 -62% 1 -95%
Bulgaria 2,84 -18% 491 -6% 0 11576 -19%
Croatia 1,35 -19% 190 -9% 47 -84% 21622 -10%
Cyprus 0,55 -2% 42 -2% 0 2528 0%
Czech Rep. 3,99 -21% 329 -7% 271 -66% 1068 -36%
Denmark 1,36 -15% 117 -4% 10 -70% 4128 -2%
Estonia 0,39 -8% 26 -4% 0 3062 -31%
Finland 1,17 -6% 67 -3% 0 5060 -31%
France 19,70 -15% 1539 -5% 216 -91% 81731 -31%
Germany 26,72 -19% 2439 -6% 615 -83% 32316 -35%
Greece 4,97 -16% 595 -5% 75 -50% 53785 -2%
Hungary 3,85 -22% 465 -8% 430 -60% 15882 -14%
Ireland 0,74 -9% 47 -4% 0 -91% 381 -35%
Italy 24,19 -22% 3259 -6% 2 -96% 36140 -34%
Latvia 0,71 -12% 61 -3% 577 -45% 22428 -15%
Lithuania 1,15 -14% 95 -5% 5357 -7% 18044 -5%
Luxembourg 0,18 -17% 11 0% 3 -97% 1071 -4%
Malta 0,12 -7% 17 -6% 0 0
Netherlands 5,94 -14% 308 -5% 3213 -14% 3508 -10%
Poland 20,55 -23% 1040 -7% 5693 -65% 43383 -26%
Portugal 2,72 -25% 415 -5% 132 -30% 30318 -7%
Romania 8,74 -22% 955 -7% 0 -100% 82945 -6%
Slovakia 2,04 -24% 177 -8% 42 -91% 18206 -6%
Slovenia 0,60 -26% 73 -9% 0 -100% 417 -78%
Spain 12,69 -21% 1473 -4% 1 -97% 188858 -6%
Sweden 1,66 -8% 159 -4% 4012 -19% 30859 -29%
Un. Kingdom 14,59 -23% 1103 -5% 338 -59% 1572 -60%
EU-28 170,35 -20% 16007 -6% 21047 -50% 718011 -18%
236 A PPENDIX 7.7 I NDICATIVE EMISSION TRAJECTORY TOWARDS ACHIEVING THE LONG -
TERM OBJECTIVE IN 2050
SO2 emissions, kiloton. Indicative beyond 2025
2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Austria 12 11 9 8 8 7
Belgium 46 43 40 38 35 33
Bulgaria 81 61 46 34 26 20
Croatia 9 8 7 6 5 5
Cyprus 1 1 1 1 1 1
Czech Rep. 65 53 43 34 28 22
Denmark 9 9 8 8 7 7
Estonia 20 18 17 16 15 14
Finland 63 55 49 43 38 33
France 103 94 87 79 73 67
Germany 295 245 203 169 140 116
Greece 52 40 31 24 20 15
Hungary 17 15 14 12 11 10
Ireland 13 10 8 7 5 4
Italy 93 85 77 70 64 58
Latvia 3 3 2 2 2 2
Lithuania 11 10 10 9 9 8
Luxembourg 1 1 1 1 1 1
Malta 0 0 0 0 0 0
Netherlands 30 27 24 22 19 17
Poland 332 252 191 145 110 83
Portugal 23 21 19 17 15 13
Romania 55 44 36 29 23 19
Slovakia 20 18 17 16 15 14
Slovenia 5 4 4 3 3 3
Spain 152 134 119 105 93 82
Sweden 30 30 29 28 27 26
Un. Kingdom 153 127 105 88 73 60
EU-28 1697 1437 1217 1030 873 739
237
NOx emissions, kiloton. Indicative beyond 2025
2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Austria 71 60 50 42 36 30
Belgium 123 108 95 84 73 64
Bulgaria 63 54 47 41 35 30
Croatia 27 22 17 14 11 9
Cyprus 7 6 5 4 4 3
Czech Rep. 114 96 81 69 58 49
Denmark 63 56 49 43 38 34
Estonia 18 15 12 10 8 7
Finland 110 92 77 64 53 44
France 453 391 338 292 252 218
Germany 517 438 372 315 268 227
Greece 129 116 103 93 83 74
Hungary 53 45 38 32 28 23
Ireland 54 45 38 31 26 22
Italy 447 399 357 319 285 255
Latvia 22 18 15 13 11 9
Lithuania 29 24 19 16 13 11
Luxembourg 13 10 7 6 4 3
Malta 1 1 1 1 1 0
Netherlands 134 124 115 107 99 91
Poland 398 336 283 238 201 169
Portugal 76 68 60 54 48 43
Romania 111 95 81 69 59 50
Slovakia 42 37 33 29 25 22
Slovenia 17 13 11 9 7 6
Spain 418 348 289 241 200 167
Sweden 82 74 66 60 54 49
Un. Kingdom 450 383 327 279 238 203
EU-28 4043 3481 2997 2581 2222 1913
238
VOC emissions, kiloton. Indicative beyond 2025
2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Austria 90 78 68 60 52 45
Belgium 88 81 75 69 64 59
Bulgaria 55 45 38 31 26 21
Croatia 38 34 30 27 25 22
Cyprus 4 4 3 3 2 2
Czech Rep. 113 98 84 73 63 54
Denmark 54 48 43 38 34 30
Estonia 26 21 16 13 10 8
Finland 95 82 71 61 52 45
France 571 517 468 423 383 347
Germany 715 653 597 545 498 455
Greece 92 80 69 60 52 45
Hungary 63 55 47 41 36 31
Ireland 43 36 30 26 22 18
Italy 566 505 450 401 357 318
Latvia 30 24 20 16 13 11
Lithuania 34 29 24 20 17 14
Luxembourg 5 5 4 3 3 3
Malta 3 2 2 2 2 1
Netherlands 135 123 112 102 93 85
Poland 286 241 203 171 144 122
Portugal 118 108 99 90 83 76
Romania 171 143 120 100 84 70
Slovakia 45 40 35 30 26 23
Slovenia 15 14 12 11 10 9
Spain 488 451 417 385 356 329
Sweden 136 123 111 100 90 81
Un. Kingdom 550 508 470 434 401 370
EU-28 4630 4155 3728 3346 3002 2694
239
PM2,5 emissions, kiloton. Indicative beyond 2025
2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Austria 11 11 10 9 9 8
Belgium 15 15 14 14 13 13
Bulgaria 14 12 10 9 7 6
Croatia 5 4 4 3 3 2
Cyprus 1 1 1 1 1 1
Czech Rep. 23 19 16 13 11 9
Denmark 11 9 8 7 6 5
Estonia 10 7 5 3 2 1
Finland 18 15 13 11 9 8
France 154 141 130 119 109 100
Germany 73 68 63 58 54 50
Greece 16 15 14 14 13 13
Hungary 11 10 9 8 8 7
Ireland 9 8 7 7 6 5
Italy 85 74 65 57 50 43
Latvia 9 6 5 3 2 2
Lithuania 7 6 5 4 3 3
Luxembourg 2 2 2 2 1 1
Malta 0 0 0 0 0 0
Netherlands 15 14 13 12 11 10
Poland 154 117 89 68 51 39
Portugal 19 18 17 16 15 14
Romania 44 36 29 24 19 16
Slovakia 12 11 9 8 7 6
Slovenia 2 2 2 2 2 2
Spain 61 58 54 51 48 46
Sweden 21 19 17 16 14 13
Un. Kingdom 46 44 41 39 37 34
EU-28 848 750 663 586 518 458
240
NH3 emissions, kiloton. Indicative beyond 2025
2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Austria 50 46 42 38 35 32
Belgium 62 59 56 53 50 48
Bulgaria 58 56 54 52 51 49
Croatia 20 18 17 15 14 13
Cyprus 5 4 4 4 3 3
Czech Rep. 52 50 48 46 44 43
Denmark 44 42 40 38 36 34
Estonia 9 8 8 7 7 6
Finland 27 26 24 22 20 19
France 463 436 411 387 365 343
Germany 318 296 275 256 238 222
Greece 41 38 36 34 33 31
Hungary 48 45 42 39 36 33
Ireland 89 84 80 76 72 68
Italy 298 280 264 249 234 221
Latvia 13 12 11 10 10 9
Lithuania 40 39 35 32 29 26
Luxembourg 5 4 4 4 4 4
Malta 1 1 1 1 1 1
Netherlands 111 107 104 101 98 95
Poland 243 226 211 196 183 170
Portugal 55 53 51 49 47 45
Romania 115 103 92 83 74 67
Slovakia 17 16 15 14 13 12
Slovenia 14 13 12 11 10 9
Spain 256 240 225 211 198 185
Sweden 43 41 39 38 36 34
Un. Kingdom 240 233 225 218 211 204
EU-28 2740 2579 2428 2286 2151 2025
241
ANNEX 8 S ENSITIVITY ANALYSES AND RISK ASSESSMENTS
The interim objectives established in Chapter 6 are tested for robustness against variations of real-world conditions away from the assumptions used in the modelling exercise. This is done by conducting a series of sensitivity analyses.
1. T ESTING THE ROBUSTNESS OF THE CENTRAL CASE FOR CHANGES TO THE TARGET
YEAR
The target year of 2025 should be tested to ensure that it does not introduce any economic sub-optimality vis-a-vis a later target year (of 2030). The following options were identified.
Option 1 Option 2 Option 3
2030, with Central Target Year 2025 2030 intermediate
milestone for 2025
The sub-optimality test is done in two steps:
The first step test is to compare impact reduction costs in 2025 and in 2030 to determine if structural changes occurring during the period make certain cheaper pollution reduction options available in 2030, which were not in 2025. This has been addressed firstly by examining if the wedge between baseline and maximum technically feasible reduction becomes wider in 2030 than in 2025, which would indicate that additional potential measures come on stream; and secondly by calculating the cost-effectiveness of avoided premature deaths in 2025 and 2030 for Options 6A, 6B, 6C and 6D.
1.Baseline 6A 6B 6C 6E.MTFR
2025 Premature deaths 307000 286000 265000 245000 225000
cost, million € 221 1202 4629 47007
reduction potential 82000
cost per avoided premature death, M€ 0,010 0,028 0,074 0,57
2030 Premature deaths 304000 284000 263000 243000 218000
cost, million € 212 1032 4182 50582
reduction potential 86000
cost per avoided premature death, M€ 0,010 0,025 0,69 0,59
While the baseline impacts are almost unchanged (1% lower) in 2030 than in 2025, the further reduction potential increases slightly (86 vs. 80 thousand premature deaths avoided). Average reduction costs per additional life saved are in the same range in 2030 and in 2025 for all gap closure levels. In fact, the 2025 and 2030 options include exactly the same technical measures, and the reason why average cost-effectiveness shows marginal changes
242
between the two years is that the shares of the same measures in the overall reduction strategy change. Indeed the largest differences between the 2025 and 2030 options are in the residential combustion sector, where costs fall some 30% due to less pollution control measures needed as a consequence of fuel switching away from coal. On the other hand, intensification of small-scale biomass use makes the costs to close the entire gap to the technical potential (MTFR) higher than in 2025. It is concluded that the structural changes occurring between 2025 and 2030 do not make cheaper reduction options available.
The second step is to compare the technical measures required to achieve the gap-closure in 2025 with the structural changes occurring between 2025 and 2030: any measures that emerge as cost effective in 2025 but are not necessary in 2030 are in principle regret measures, as they would give raise to stranded costs on the extended (2030) timetable because certain declining activities are shut down or replaced.
As a rough illustrative example, consider the above methodology applied to coal-fired power generation. Broadly speaking a regret investment is where an abatement measure is applied to meet the 2025 reduction target, but the plant in question is retired between 2025 and 2030, and hence no abatement on it would be needed in 2030. But note that the investment is only a regret investment if the abatement equipment itself needs to be retired prematurely - if the equipment would in any case come to the end of its natural life before the plant was retired, there would be no wasted investment. Thus, regret investments are those equipment sets that are applied to plants that will be retired between 2025 and 2030, and where the equipment itself is retired early as a result. To identify these, we first take the number of sets (defined as thermal power capacity) of abatement equipment applied to meet the 2025 target, and check how many are still operational in 2030 (assuming they are applied gradually to the coal capacity over the period 2015-2025, and have a certain normal working life). We then compare these 2025 ‘survivors’ with the number of sets of abatement equipment needed on a 2030 scenario to control the entire existing capacity. The excess constitutes the regret investments. The analysis was performed for each sector, and as a headline indicator for potential regret measures, the annualised costs are presented.
The following analysis refers to the central case option 6C* defined in Error! Reference source not found. of section 6.3.2; any emerging regret measures should be interpreted as an upper limit for any options less ambitious than 6C*. In this scenario, the rapid capital turnover assumed in the draft PRIMES2012-3 energy scenario, a small share of the additional measures of Option 6C* could turn out as regret investments in 2030. In total, these questionable measures affect 7 kt of SO2 (i.e., 1.2% of the additional 6C* reductions), of which 5 kt in the UK, 0.5 kt NOx (0.4% of the 6C* reductions) and 2.3 kt PM2.5 (2.5% of the 6C* improvements). Costs associated with these regret measures account for 0.6% of the costs of the 6C* Option. However, 50% of these costs emerge in a single country, the UK,
where the PRIMES 2012-3 1 reference scenario suggests an almost complete phase-out of coal
from power generation between 2025 and 2030. For the remaining 27 Member States, regret measures account on average for 0.3% of the costs of all 6C* measures.
Considering also the uncertainties around the baseline projection, it is concluded that the emission controls of the 6C* Option lead to only marginal potential regret investments.
1 The current analysis is based on the most recent available reference energy scenario, which is the January
2013 draft that was consulted with the Member States in early 2013.
243
2. I NTERACTION WITH THE CLIMATE AND ENERGY PACKAGE
The previous section addresses the needs for air policy to carefully take into account the possible mismatches with investment cycles. This is even more important in the light of the future climate and energy policy framework, which may be expected to result in even deeper restructuring of the energy system than foreseen in the most recent PRIMES 2012-3 reference scenario, which already assumes the achievement of rather ambitious renewable energy targets by 2020 as well as substantial progress in energy efficiency, if not full achievement of the 20% target. It is therefore important to examine the possible interactions between air pollution reduction policy and a climate and energy policy of greater stringency. The effects of climate change mitigation policy in the main sectors in the relevant short-to-medium timescale, and the resulting interactions with air pollution reduction, are summarised as follows:
• Road transport sector: decarbonisation of the transport sector can operate at multiple levels, including the improvement of public transport options to reduce the overall vehicle/ton-km demand; the development of alternative vehicles and vehicle infrastructure, such as hybrids, plug-in hybrids and electric vehicles (hydrogen fuel cell vehicles in the longer term); and the promotion of available vehicles with lower fuel consumption. All these options are win-win solutions for climate and air quality, with the exception of the promotion of light-duty diesel vehicles which –though marginally better than gasoline vehicles on fuel efficiency- in the current situation emit a disproportionately higher amount of NOx. Recent advancements in gasoline engine technology (Gasoline Direct Injection, or GDI) have also enabled the development of highly fuel efficient gasoline engines, which however emit a large number of ultrafine particles (particle emissions from conventional gasoline engines are quasi-nil). In conclusion, decarbonisation of the transport sector can deliver strong benefits also for air quality, but conventional vehicles will maintain an important share of the market in the foreseeable future and will still need effective pollution control, in particular to manage the air quality implications of diesels and GDI.
• Non-road transport: Since in the short term technological breakthrough are not expected and currently there are limited technical options to specifically reduce NOx and PM emission from commercial aviation, only marine shipping is considered. LNG is a viable option to reduce CO2 emissions and at the same time SO2 and NOx emissions with no or reduced need for after-treatment. In principle, investment for pollution abatement installed on ships could become redundant if the vessel or its engine were scrapped a few years later to be substituted by LNG technology. However, the commissioning of large ships is planned long enough in advance to take into adequately account the lifetime of pollution abatement equipment.
• Residential sector: in a decarbonising world, the residential sector will reduce its energy use by more efficient (electrical) energy using products, by improving the energy performance of buildings for temperature control, and by using carbon-lean and carbonfree heating technologies. Among these options, all are win-win solutions for climate and air quality, with the exception of the promotion of domestic use of biomass. Uncontrolled combustion of biomass, in fact, is a potent source of fine particles, black carbon, and poly-aromatic hydrocarbons. A certain share of domestic biomass use can be compatible with air quality objectives, but a prerequisite is that expansion of such capacity happen with high standards in place: in order to avoid the potential high costs to
244
replace highly polluting stoves and boilers a few years after installation, it must be considered a matter of priority to put in place stringent emission standards for smallscale appliances before they capture higher market shares. The contrary would generate sunk costs or unacceptable public health outcome.
• Electricity supply sector: decarbonisation of the power sector includes improved conversion efficiency, e.g. by expanded CHP capacity, switching to lower carbon fuels, switching to renewable sources, and more efficient and smarter transmission grids. Renewable sources are not only carbon neutral but also pollution free, again with the exception of biomass; however, strict regulation for large combustion plants can be an effective enabling factor for tapping the biomass potential while limiting to a minimum the detrimental consequences on human health. It is noteworthy, however, that a possible greater share of decentralised power sources in future could increase the share of combustion in installations smaller than 50MWTh, which are currently not regulated at EU level. Again, it will be important to have in place adequately high emission standards before such capacity expansion occurs, as it would be much more costly to retrofit the same installations at a later time. Biomass caveat aside, switching from coal plants to natural gas or to carbon-free sources provides substantial co-benefits for air quality. In principle, investment for pollution abatement installed on existing coal plants could be made redundant if there was a plan to shut down the plant a few years later and to substitute it by alternative technology. However, planning and building new power plants requires a long time, and national energy plans (which may include turning off old coal plants) can provide the necessary stability to take rational investment decisions on pollution abatement equipment taking into account its useful lifetime.
• Industry: substitution possibilities in energy intensive industries are more limited than in the power sector, as primary processes in iron & steel or cement making cannot be easily substituted by different techniques. The refinery sector is a special case, as decarbonisation will substantially reduce demand for oil products with consequent impacts for activity in the sector. However, the transition will take a long time, and the effect of climate policy on the demand for refinery products can be forecast sufficiently in advance to effectively plan the operation and investment requirements of the existing refining capacity.
• Solvents: solvent applications are not significantly affected by climate mitigation policy; there are no evident trade-offs between climate and air pollution policy. Limiting VOC emissions, conversely, reduces ozone formation which is also a potent short-lived climate forcer.
• Agriculture: most of air pollution reduction measures addressing agriculture are related to technical measures to control ammonia emissions. These measures are largely applicable irrespective of the livestock numbers or of other key parameters influencing methane emissions, and the interactions between climate and air policies as regards agricultural measures are not significant, with the exception of the win-win effect of methane reduction, which is not only a greenhouse gas but also a precursor of hemispheric background ozone.
In conclusion, there are substantial interactions between climate change and air pollution policies. A more ambitious climate policy is expected to make reaching the new air quality objectives cheaper by removing highly polluting sources such as coal plants or reducing
245
domestic coal use; however, expanded biomass combustion can result in detrimental health impacts unless sufficiently stringent emission standards are put in place. Some sectors, such as the power and refineries sectors, may face in principle the risk that accelerated decarbonisation of electricity supply and of the transport sector could result in early retirement of large capacities and make redundant any additional pollution abatement investments on those plants. However, any future low-carbon economy roadmap scenario would seek to develop a cost-effective pathway to the agreed climate targets taking into account the need to minimise stranded cost risks; furthermore, the time horizon of the proposed air quality policy targets (2025-2030) will give sufficient time for plant operators to develop rational investment plans that give full value to the invested capital.
246
3. E MISSION REDUCTIONS DELIVERED BY FURTHER CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION
POLICY
The Commission work programme for 2013 foresees a new climate and energy framework for the 2030 time horizon which should deliver benefits in terms of air quality. The form of this policy is not clear at the time of writing, but the following analysis has assumed a reduction in domestic GHG emissions below 1990 levels by 25% in 2020 and by 40% in
2030. 2
Based on this, decarbonisation measures alone could reduce health impacts from PM2,5 by approximately 5% in 2030 and 10% in 2050 compared to the current legislation baseline. This compares with reductions from additional air pollution measures of around 30% in both years. Decarbonisation of the economy has a more substantial impact on acidification and ground-level ozone, delivering as much as two thirds of the MTFR reductions by 2050. Decarbonisation would reduce eutrophication impacts only marginally.
Thus while the impacts of decarbonisation are clearly positive for air, the limited reductions PM and eutrophication mean that climate policy alone would not be sufficient to achieve the long-term air quality objective by 2050.
The following charts show the impact reductions that would be achieved by the baseline in the absence of further policies , by climate decarbonisation policy, by air pollution control measures (MTFR), and by a Maximum control effort (MCE) trajectory that combines decarbonisation and air pollution control measures; the additional reduction potential on eutrophication is in this case due to assumptions on hypothetical behavioural change reducing meat consumption in Europe:
2 Recent IIASA analysis (See Chapter 3.1, TSAP Report #6, IIASA, 2012B) based on the Global Climate
Action/ effective technology scenario developed for the low carbon economy roadmap (SEC(2011) 288 final )
247
Figure A8.1: Impact reductions in the long term under different trajectories: current legisaltion (CLE) baseline and MTFR (blue lines), decarbonisation and MCE (red lines)
Loss in statistical life expectancy from PM2,5 Premature deaths due to ground-level ozone
10 35000
Baseline - CLE Baseline - CLE 9
Baseline - MTFR 30000 Baseline - MTFR 8 TSAP target TSAP target
Decarb - CLE r Decarb - CLE
7 ea 25000 MCE /y MCE
6 at
hs
s de 20000 th
on 5 tu
re
M ma
4 re
15000
f p s o 3 se
Ca 10000
2
5000 1
0 0
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
Forest acidification (unprotected area) Ecosystems eutrophication (unprotected area)
250 1400
Baseline - CLE Baseline - CLE
Baseline - MTFR 1200 Baseline - MTFR 200 TSAP target TSAP target
Decarb - CLE Decarb - CLE 1000
MCE MCE
150 800
m2 m2
1000 k 1000 k 600
100
400
50
200
0 0
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
4. C HANGES TO THE GROWTH PROJECTIONS AND TO PROGRESS IN ENERGY
EFFICIENCY AND RENEWABLES
Emissions are strongly correlated with economic activity, and higher growth would entail higher levels of baseline emissions. Interim objectives, although initially defined in terms of gap closure, will for policy purposes be expressed in terms of absolute impacts. Thus the objectives must be tested to ensure that the absolute impact reductions in question are still achievable on a higher-growth scenario. The concept is illustrated in Figure A8.2 below.
248
Figure A8.2: Achievability of environmental objectives on a higher growth scenario
The red lines illustrate the
wedge between current legislation emissions and MTFR in the reference case.
The blue lines represent the same wedge under a higher
growth assumption. The gap closure target defined under
reference projections would become in a higher growth
case closer to the MTFR and consequently more
expensive as additional measures would be required
to achieve it .
To do this, emission reductions and associated control costs for achieving the environmental targets of the central scenario in absolute terms (i.e., in absolute YOLLs, km2, etc.) are calculated again starting from an alternative baseline representing higher growth. The scenario chosen for this purpose is the previous PRIMES 2010 reference scenario, which assumes GDP in 2025 and 2030 approximately 7% higher than in the PRIMES 2012-3 reference case (or an average annual growth rate 0,35% higher). Achievability of the targets under the PRIMES 2010 trajectory has been checked for different scenario variants that would achieve 75% gap closure on the PM mortality objective and increasingly stringent objectives on ozone and eutrophication targets. The conclusions are a fortiori valid for options closer to the baseline trajectory.
In addition to the PRIMES 2010 trajectory, sensitivity analyses were also done with PRIMES energy results of the 2012-3 EU "Baseline with adopted measures" scenario. This is a scenario done for climate policy purposes, which is similar to the corresponding reference scenario except in assumptions on renewable energy and energy efficiency policies. The 2012-3 reference case assumes that the EU renewable energy targets will be fully met and that the Energy Efficiency Directive (EED) adopted in 2012 is fully implemented. In the Baseline with adopted measures the deployment of renewables depends on currently adopted national policies and measures and the EED is not included insofar as effects on GHG emissions depend on the way in which transposition into national measures will take place. The analysis indicates therefore how much more expensive it would be to meet air pollution reduction objectives if progress on renewables and energy efficiency would turn out to be less than in the reference case.
Under the PRIMES2012-3 Baseline trajectory, the entire range of objectives would still be achievable, albeit at moderately higher costs (6-8% more for eutrophication reductions in the range 80-90% gap closure. Summary figures for these sensitivity analyses are presented in table A8.1.
249
Table A8.1: Impact reduction targets and emission control costs (million €/yr) in 2025 of different targets optimized for the trajectories PRIMES 2012-3 reference, PRIMES 2012-3 baseline, and PRIMES 2010 reference. Changes in costs are compared to current legislation costs. INF indicates target infeasible.
Base Ozone E80 E82,5 E85 E90 E95 E99,5
Gap closure:
PM mortality 75% 75% 75% 75% 75% 75% 75% 75%
Ozone NA 46% 46% 46% 46% 46% 46% 46%
Eutrophication NA NA 80% 82,50% 85% 90% 95% 99,50%
compliance cost
P2012-3 reference 4.629 4.648 4.680 4.766 4.884 5.195 5.971 9.653
P2012-3 baseline 5.036 5.053 5.069 5.127 5.228 5.493 6.150 8.936
P2010 reference 3.988 4.600 6.201 7.304 10.409 INF INF INF
However, it must be noted that the PRIMES 2010 and PRIMES 2012 scenarios differ in much more than only growth projections. The projected energy mix is different, for instance as a reflection of the improved understanding of the outcome of existing energy and climate mitigation policies and the inclusion of recent energy trends. As a result, PRIMES 2010 provides valuable information and a useful test of the feasibility of objectives in an uncertain future, but the interpretation of comparative emission control costs in detail requires further discussion:
For the ‘health only’ target (base), additional emission control costs (on top of those for current legislation) amount to 4.6 billion €/yr for the PRIMES 2012 scenario, and to close to 4 billion € under the P2010 trajectory. This would be counter-intuitive for an alternative scenario driven by higher growth only, and is a consequence of the higher use of biomass in the residential sector in P2012, which causes more emissions of primary PM2.5 which, when originating from small sources, are more expensive to abate than the emissions of secondary PM2.5 precursors (i.e., SO 2 , NO x , etc.) targeted in the P2010 case.
However, costs eventually increase faster for additional improvements of, eutrophication under P2010 (Figure A8.3). For the P2012 case, costs for further eutrophication improvements rise slowly until about 90% gap closure. For the P2010 trajectory, additional costs on top of the health-only case rapidly increase from 1.6 for the 80% case to 5.8 billion €/yr for the 85% case, while the range of 90% and beyond would not be feasible.
250
Figure A8.3: Variation of emission control costs (on top of the costs for the CLE scenarios) for achievements of health and environmental targets under the P2012 reference and baseline, and P2010 trajectories
While in the PRIMES 2012-3 reference case the pollution control expenditure increases by €32M and €118M respectively when moving to 80% and 82,5% eutrophication gap closure (even less in the PRIMES 2012-3 baseline), with the PRIMES 2010 assumptions the costs increase by €1,6bn and €2,7bn respectively.
This striking difference is entirely due to higher livestock number projections in the PRIMES 2010 scenario, which in turn drive higher ammonia emissions and higher costs to bring them down to the target levels identified by the pollution reduction objectives of the various options: on PRIMES 2010, the introduction of 80% and 82,5 eutrophication gap closure requires additional costs to control ammonia of €2,1bn and 2,9bn respectively (even higher than the €1,6bn and 2,7bn total cost increase, meaning that some other sectors would reduce their effort slightly). With 85% eutrophication gap closure, the ammonia reduction potential would be almost entirely exhausted, driving additional NOx reductions for almost €4bn to reach this eutrophication reduction target. For the same reason, stricter eutrophication reduction targets would not be achievable on PRIMES 2010.
The analysis presented above examines whether or not certain levels of environmental objectives would be feasible under economic growth and energy system assumptions diverging from the central ones, and how costly it would be to achieve them. A further question is the feasibility and compliance cost relate to the individual emission reduction commitments identified as most cost-effective under reference assumptions. In this context, the cost of achieving the emission ceilings of the central case option 6C* (see Annex 7, Appendix 7.4) has been calculated under the PRIMES 2012-3 "Baseline with adopted measures" assumptions (see above). All ceilings have been assessed to be within the feasible range; Table A8.2 summarises the resulting compliance costs.
251
Table A8.2: Costs of achieving the C6* emission ceilings in the EU28 in 2025 under the PRIMES 2012-3 reference and baseline with adopted measures assumptions
EU-28 4680 5774 1094
SNAP sector ref BL diff. SNAP sector ref BL diff.
Power generation 500 536 36 Solvent use 63 69 5
Domestic sector 1611 2609 998 Road transport 0 0 0
Industrial combust. 610 650 40 Non-road mobile 142 169 27
Industrial processes 384 393 9 Waste treatment 9 9 0
Fuel extraction 6 6 0 Agriculture 1356 1334 -22
All Economy 4680 5774 1094
Table A8.2 shows that compliance costs would be 1094 M€/yr (23% higher), almost entirely (998 M€/year) for pollution abatement in residential combustion, demonstrating the high synergetic potential of energy efficiency measures to curb energy demand and associated pollution from buildings.
5. B URDEN SHARING BETWEEN M EMBER S TATES
Option 6C* (Error! Reference source not found.) would require some 0,03% of the EU's GDP for expenditure in additional pollution abatement measures. However, the distribution of effort across Member States varies from 0,003% of GDP in Sweden to 0,168% of GDP in Bulgaria. This is a reflection both of different absolute GDP levels (the cost of the same piece of equipment would represent a higher share of GDP in a lower-income country); and of differences in past effort (a smaller reduction potential in countries with a longer pollution control tradition).
The effect of capping the direct additional expenditure as a percentage of GDP was assessed. The reduced costs for the capped Member States entails increased costs for other Member States, in particular neighbouring Member States upwind of those that reduce their effort, in order to meet the same objectives, and lower cost-effectiveness overall.
Table A8.3: Costs of achieving the C6* emission ceilings in the Member States in 2025 under the PRIMES 2012-3 reference and baseline with adopted measures
Option 6C* C15 (<= 0.16%) C16 (<=0.15%) changes relative to Option 6C*
M€ % of GDP M€ % of GDP M€ % of GDP <0,16% <0,15%
Austria 100,0 0,028 99,3 0,028 222,1 0,062 Austria -1% 122%
Belgium 114,5 0,026 114,4 0,026 95,6 0,022 Belgium 0% -16%
Bulgaria 80,7 0,168 76,7 0,160 71,9 0,150 Bulgaria -5% -11%
Croatia 39,8 0,064 39,0 0,063 93,3 0,150 Croatia -2% 135%
Cyprus 1,2 0,006 1,0 0,005 1,0 0,005 Cyprus -14% -16%
Czech Rep. 118,6 0,059 117,5 0,059 300,8 0,150 Czech Rep. -1% 154%
Denmark 32,5 0,011 32,5 0,011 44,3 0,015 Denmark 0% 36%
Estonia 7,4 0,034 7,4 0,035 7,8 0,036 Estonia 0% 5%
Finland 13,7 0,006 13,7 0,006 15,3 0,007 Finland 0% 12%
252
France 378,0 0,015 378,1 0,015 461,1 0,019 France 0% 22%
Germany 855,8 0,029 855,9 0,029 2.189,4 0,075 Germany 0% 156%
Greece 82,3 0,034 109,1 0,045 361,0 0,150 Greece 32% 338%
Hungary 93,0 0,080 101,3 0,087 173,8 0,150 Hungary 9% 87%
Ireland 26,1 0,012 26,0 0,012 20,2 0,009 Ireland 0% -23%
Italy 595,2 0,033 594,1 0,033 1.653,3 0,091 Italy 0% 178%
Latvia 19,9 0,075 19,9 0,075 19,7 0,075 Latvia 0% -1%
Lithuania 28,0 0,073 27,8 0,073 57,2 0,150 Lithuania -1% 104%
Luxembourg 2,9 0,005 2,9 0,005 1,6 0,003 Luxembourg 0% -45%
Malta 0,4 0,005 0,4 0,005 0,3 0,004 Malta -5% -17%
Netherlands 62,7 0,009 62,7 0,009 60,7 0,008 Netherlands 0% -3%
Poland 736,7 0,142 736,8 0,142 780,3 0,150 Poland 0% 6%
Portugal 92,2 0,046 92,3 0,046 88,7 0,045 Portugal 0% -4%
Romania 265,7 0,159 268,1 0,160 251,4 0,150 Romania 1% -5%
Slovak Rep. 86,0 0,090 85,3 0,089 143,3 0,150 Slovak Rep. -1% 67%
Slovenia 50,5 0,112 50,4 0,112 49,6 0,110 Slovenia 0% -2%
Spain 268,6 0,019 268,4 0,019 270,0 0,019 Spain 0% 1%
Sweden 15,8 0,003 15,8 0,003 14,6 0,003 Sweden 0% -8%
Un. Kingdom 512,0 0,023 512,0 0,023 616,6 0,028 Un. Kingdom 0% 20%
EU-28 4.680,2 0,030 4.708,6 0,031 8.065,0 0,052 EU-28 1% 72%
Maximum 0,168 0,160 0,150
Table A8.3 shows the cost changes per Member state and for the EU28 when setting an upper bound to the maximum effort per country to a fixed percentage of GDP, while ensuring that all four main environmental objectives (PM-health, ozone, eutrophication and acidification) are met in each country. Setting a limit of 0,16% would in primis reduce the effort for Bulgaria for € 4M, and require a redistribution of effort resulting in costs for the EU28 28 M€ higher overall. Limiting the maximum effort at 0,15% would further save Bulgaria 5 M€ and Romania 17 M€, but overall costs for the EU would balloon to €3,7bn higher. This indicates that the scope for limiting individual efforts while maintaining the environmental and health benefits of option 6C* in all Member States is negligible, and confirms that the effort required on option 6C* is well balanced across Member States.
6. F URTHER EMISSION CONTROLS FROM INTERNATIONAL MARITIME SHIPPING
This section examines whether further reductions of ship emissions (i.e. beyond the emission reductions that will be delivered by the recently amended Directive on the sulphur content of marine fuels 2012/33/EU, and existing international standards in relation to SOx and NOx emissions as established in Annex VI to the MARPOL Convention) could emerge as costeffective means for achieving the environmental objectives of the revised TSAP, i.e., to what extent they could substitute more expensive measures at land-based sources. The environmental objectives are those of the central case option 6C*.
For the purpose of this sensitivity analysis, two alternative scenarios cases are calculated: Scenario SN1 assumes sulphur and nitrogen emission control areas (SECAs and NECAs) in the 200 nautical miles zones (EEZ, Exclusive Economic Zone) of all EU countries. This
253
24% cut in NO x . Scenario SN2 excludes further SECAs and foresees only the introduction of
NECAs in EEZ of all EU countries (24% cut in NOx).
Table A8.4: SO 2 and NOx emission from marine activities in 2005 and 2025; baseline, a scenario with SECAs and NECAs in the EU’s EEZs, and a variant with NECAs only; unit: kilotons
SO2 Baseline SN1 SN2 NOx Baseline SN1 SN2
2005 2025 SECA-NECA NECA only 2005 2025 SECA-NECA NECA only
Baltic Sea 130 7 7 7 Baltic Sea 220 193 131 131
Bay of Biscay 282 72 16 72 Bay of Biscay 474 457 311 311
Black Sea 27 7 6 7 Black Sea 47 42 38 38
Celtic Sea 14 2 1 2 Celtic Sea 22 19 13 13
Mediterranean Sea 764 183 104 183 Mediterranean Sea 1294 1186 963 963
North Sea 309 16 16 16 North Sea 518 476 323 323
Rest of NE Atlantic 31 8 8 8 Rest of NE Atlantic 54 51 51 51
(within EMEP grid) (within EMEP grid)
Rest of NE Atlantic 112 28 14 28 Rest of NE Atlantic 192 184 144 144
(outside EMEP grid) (outside EMEP grid)
Total 1668 321 171 321 Total 2821 2606 1973 1973
The additional measures for SECAs and NECAs reduce costs for these land-based sources in
2025 by 814 million €/yr in the SN1 scenario, and by 528 million €/yr in Scenario SN2
(Table A8.5). At the same time, the estimated costs for the NECA 3 are of 564 million €/yr in
2025. For SECAs in the 200 nm zones of all EU countries, cost estimates range between 1.3 billion €/yr in case scrubber-based compliance is used and 2.8 billion €/yr for use of low sulphur fuel.
Compared to the 6C*, total emission control costs (of land-based and marine sources) would increase by 10-40% in the SN1 case, and by less than 1% in SN2 with NECA only.
In conclusion, with the current assumptions on costs for low sulphur fuels, packages of
SECAs and NECAs in the 200 nm zones of the EU Member States would be overall more expensive than some land-based measures available to achieve the targets of the base case. Scrubber-based compliance would substantially reduce the SECA costs, but would not close the cost-effectiveness gap in full compared to land-based emission reductions; note that this assessment is based on the reduction of impacts on land and does not take into consideration any of the additional benefits for the marine/coastal environment.
On the other hand, emission reductions associated with the designation of NECAs would be essentially as cost-effective as emission reductions on land, with a less than 1% difference in total pollution control costs which is well within the uncertainty range of the costs estimates, and indicates seaborne NOx reductions as an economically attractive option for the future.
3 “ Specific evaluation of emissions from shipping including assessment for the establishment of possible new
emission control areas in European Seas (VITO, 2013)
254
Table A8.5: Comparison of emissions (kilotons) and emission control costs (million €/yr) of scenarios SN1 and SN2 for the reduction of emissions from international marine shipping. Changes in emissions refer to 2005, changes in costs to the costs of Option 1 (Baseline.)
2005 Option 1 base case SN1 SN2
SO2 7874 2520 1769 1773 1767
-68% -77% -77% -77%
NOx 11358 4588 4020 4125 4107
-60% -65% -64% -64%
PM2.5 1706 1274 859 859 865
-25% -49% -49% -49%
NH3 3942 3733 2765 2860 2842
-5% -30% -27% -28%
VOC 9312 5558 4593 4659 4619
-40% -51% -50% -50%
Costs for land-based 87673 +4745 +3931 +4217
Costs ships Low S fuel 0 +2771 +564
Total costs +4745 +6702 +4781
Costs ships FGD 0 +1283 +564 4
Total costs +4745 +5214 +4781
Preliminary analysis of the cost-benefit outlook for the establishment of NECA in the Baltic sea leads indeed to conclude that NECAs could deliver substantial net benefits. The following table shows a summary of the costs and benefits (source: VITO 2013 and own elaboration) of NECA in the Baltic sea:
Table A8.6: Summary cost-benefit outlook for the establishment of NECA in the Baltic sea
Baltic Tons benefit benefit
sea Nox control per ton, benefit, CBA, per ton, benefit, CBA,
removed cost, M€ low low, M€ low high high, M€ high
2020 29,6 32,6 3500 103,6 3,2 8900 263,4 8,1
2030 93,6 74,9 3500 327,6 4,4 8900 833,0 11,1
With a marginal benefit of reducing NOx emissions at sea between €3,500 and €8,900 per ton removed 5 , the benefit-to-cost ratio for the establishment of NECA in the Baltic Sea can then be estimated between 3,2 and 8,1 in 2020 and between 4,4 and 11,1 in 2030; the economic impact assessment for the designation of a NECA in the North Sea (Danish Environment Protection Agency 2012) 6 estimated for the North Sea a benefit-to-cost ratio in the same
range (1,6-6,8) although lower 7 than the Baltic estimate.
4 The cost estimate for the NECA-only scenario is the same for low-sulphur fuel and scrubber-based
compliance, as these two sub-options are relevant for SECA but not for NECA. 5 Latest update (EMRC, forthcoming) of previous values from the analysis supporting the TSAP 2005,
(AEA, 2005), ranging between €2,500 and €6,900
6 Danish Ministry of the Environment, 2012
7 The study uses however outdated damage cost figures (AEA, 2005). The most recent update (EMRC,
forthcoming) would yield a benefit-to-cost ratio 70-80% higher.
255
Reducing NOx emissions from international shipping in the EU sea areas could in sum deliver substantial benefits, and Member States that do so would need to take less action on land-based sources to meet the health and environmental objectives of the NECD. Since the emission reduction commitments of the NECD do not cover international maritime traffic emission, the possibility to allow a voluntary offset mechanism has been envisaged. Under such mechanism, a Member State that takes measures achieving demonstrable emission reductions in an area within the 200 nm of it coastline would be allowed to deduct a certain percentage (hereinafter "offset ratio") of the emission reductions achieved in that sea area from its calculated emissions for the purpose of compliance with the NECD. The following analysis is based –by way of example- on the case of designation of the sea areas within 200 nm of the EU coastline as NECA, and addresses two questions: a) since emissions occurring at sea -being farther away from population and terrestrial ecosystems- are on average less damaging than land-based emissions, which offset ratio could be allowed, while guaranteeing the integrity of the NECD's environmental objectives? And b) how much would the Member States' NOx control costs be reduced? Tables A8.7 and A8.8 address questions a and b respectively. In this analysis it is assumed that all Member States would designate their territorial waters + EEZ as NECA; since the Member States do not currently report emissions in their EEZ, the analysis assumes that the emission reductions achieved in each of the sea areas of table A8.3 is allocated to the neighbouring Member States proportionally to their EEZ surfaces in that sea area. Three options are explored for the offset ratio: 50%, 33% and 20%
Table A8.7: integrity of environmental objectives with NECA offsets: Member states not meeting the environmental improvements delivered by Option 6C*
2025 Offset ratio 50% Offset ratio 33% Offset ratio 20%
AT, BG, HR, CY, HU, IT, SI, ES, PM Health GR, PT, RO, SK AT, BG, HR, CY, HU, IT, SI, ES IT (<1%)
BE, HR, CY, DE, LU, MA, NL, Ozone SI, SE CY none
Eutrophication none none none
Acidification HU, IT, PT, RO, SI SI none
As shown in table A8.7, allowing an offset ratio of 50% would substantially compromise the achievement of environmental objectives in the majority of Member States. At the 33% offset ratio level, the impact would be rather modest, although some land-locked Member States (which do not obtain any offset on their NOx reduction commitment) would be affected. At the 20% offset level, only one Member State (Italy) would experience a very modest impact on the PM-health objective.
Table A8.8: NOx offsets and compliance cost savings with NECA offset ratios of 50, 33 and 20%, vs emission reduction commitments of Option 6C*
2025 6C* ceiling Ceilings relative to 6C* Expenditure relative to 6C*
kt NOx 50% o.r. 33% o.r. 20% o.r. 50% o.r. 33% o.r. 20% o.r.
Austria 71 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0
Belgium 123 0,4 0,3 0,2 -0,7 -0,5 -0,3
Bulgaria 63 1,1 0,7 0,4 -1,9 -1,3 -0,8
Croatia 27 3,9 2,6 1,6 -3,8 -3,0 -2,3
256
Czech Rep. 114 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0
Denmark 63 11,0 7,3 4,4 -2,4 -2,4 -2,2
Estonia 18 2,6 1,7 1,0 0,0 0,0 0,0
Finland 110 6,1 4,0 2,4 0,0 0,0 0,0
France 453 25,4 16,8 10,2 -34,4 -28,2 -21,0
Germany 517 6,1 4,0 2,4 -18,1 -12,5 -7,6
Greece 129 34,6 22,8 13,8 -1,1 -1,1 -1,1
Hungary 53 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0
Ireland 54 1,0 0,7 0,4 -1,4 -1,0 -0,7
Italy 447 37,6 24,8 15,0 -77,7 -61,3 -46,9
Latvia 22 2,1 1,4 0,8 -0,4 -0,4 -0,3
Lithuania 29 0,4 0,3 0,2 -0,3 -0,2 -0,1
Luxembourg 13 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0
Malta 1 3,9 2,6 1,5 0,0 0,0 0,0
Netherlands 134 7,7 5,1 3,1 -5,2 -4,9 -3,2
Poland 398 2,3 1,5 0,9 -4,2 -2,8 -1,7
Portugal 76 29,8 19,7 11,9 -14,7 -13,5 -10,5
Romania 111 0,9 0,6 0,4 -1,8 -1,2 -0,7
Slovak Rep. 42 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0
Slovenia 17 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0
Spain 418 46,4 30,6 18,5 -39,3 -31,7 -23,8
Sweden 82 12,0 7,9 4,8 -0,3 -0,3 -0,3
Un. Kingdom 450 36,3 23,9 14,5 -20,5 -16,8 -12,9
EU-28 4043 278,5 183,8 111,4 -228,2 -183,0 -136,6
Table A8.8 shows that at offset ratios of 50%, 33% and 20%, total pollution control costs for land sources would decrease in 2025 by 228, 183 and 137 M€/yr (EU28). Note that in the case of smaller insular or peninsular member states (e.g. GR, CY, MT) the potential offsets may be much larger than the NOx emission reductions required by the NECD. In such cases the offset would result in much smaller pollution control cost reduction for land sources. The functioning of the offset mechanism is elucidated through the case of NECA designation, but the application of the mechanism should not be limited to this measure or to NOX only: other measures going beyond EU legislation –for instance to shift from fuel oil to LNG, or to provide clean shore-side electricity to ships at berth- could also be eligible for offsetting NOx, SO2 and PM emissions.
7. P OLICY INSTRUMENTS TO ACHIEVE THE INTERIM TARGETS : SOURCE CONTROLS AT EU LEVEL
This section examines the cost implications of implementing some of the measures identified as cost effective in the central emission reduction scenario as EU-wide source control measures rather than only setting emission ceilings through the NEC Directive and leaving the choice of technical measures entirely up to the Member States.
Leaving to the Member States the full decision as to which emission sources to control could in principle deliver the most flexible application of the technical measures best suited for the specific local conditions. However, EU source controls would help levelling the playing field and improving administrative efficiency; indeed in the public consultation 94% of
257
government respondents advocated more stringent source controls at EU level. 8 Requiring the
application of harmonised measures at EU level would result in a certain cost-effectiveness decrease, which may be well justified if proportionate in relation to the benefits. Several groups of measures have been identified, and the additional implementation cost estimated if they were taken at EU-wide scale compared to the 6C* Option implemented exclusively
through the NEC Directive. 9 The following cases were examined:
• EU-wide source controls in agriculture • EU-wide source controls for medium combustion plants (less than 50 MWth) • Selection of measures that could be covered by updated Best Available Techniques (BAT) Conclusions under the Industrial Emissions Directive (IED) for the following activities: (i) Chemicals production and solvents use, (ii) Cement & Lime production, (iii) Glass manufacturing, (iv)Petroleum Refining
7.1. EU-wide source controls in agriculture
A recent review under the IED 10 concluded that reducing emissions from manure spreading
offers the highest benefit-to-cost ratio. As a first analysis of this option, with a view to determining if and how ammonia emissions should be controlled at EU level, the following scenarios have been analysed:
• A1: Harmonised introduction of low-emission manure application techniques throughout the EU (for all farms with size larger than 15 Livestock Units)
• A2: Harmonised introduction of low-emission manure application techniques throughout
the EU for all farms with size larger than 15 Livestock Units, as well as covered storage
of manure and low-emission housing (new constructions only) for all animals except
cattle
• The central case option 6C* for 2025, as benchmark case
• Option 6C* combined with the A1 measures taken EU-wide
• Option 6C* combined with the A2 measures taken EU-wide
The summary results are shown in table A8.9:
Table A8.9: Emission reductions delivered and costs implied by EU-wide packages of ammonia control measures for manure management
cost vs baseline cost vs 6C* NH3 emission reduction
Measures A1 35 NA 92
Measures A2 54 NA 104
option 6C* 4.680 - 918
option 6C*+ A1 4.682 2 918
8 Either alone (34%) or in combination with more stringent NEC ceilings (57%)
9 Note that measures related to product standards are always assumed to be taken at EU-wide scale due to single market provisions. These include: emission standards for road vehicles and non-road machinery; solvent content of consumer products; minimum standards under the Ecodesign directive.
258
option 6C* +A2 4.691 11 918
The packages of measures A1 and A2 would deliver around 10% of the total ammonia emission reductions required by option 6C*, at a low cost (average ammonia removal cost between less than 400 € and 500 € per ton).
If national emission ceilings (delivering the objectives of option 6C*) were complemented by
EU-wide mandatory measures defined by scenarios A1 or A2, the loss of economic efficiency would be insignificant: respectively 2 or 11 M€ compared with total emission control costs of the 6C* option of 4680 M€/year (0,05 to 0,2%). This reflects the very attractive cost-effectiveness of the considered manure management measures essentially at all locations.
7.2. EU-wide source controls for Medium Combustion Plants (MCP)
Chapter 7 presents and analyses in detail the policy options to regulate air emissions from MCP (plants between 1 and 50 MW rated thermal input) at EU level. Chapter 7 concludes that a legislative instrument setting objectives that are proportionate and well-justified from a cost-benefit point of view could deliver yearly the reduction of 135 kiloton SO2, 107 kiloton NOx and 45 kiloton PM at the cost of 382 M€ (precise figures refer to 2025). Some of the associate technical measures, however, are already included in the bundle of measures that deliver the emission reductions of the policy options considered by this Impact Assessment. Table A8.10 compares the emission reductions, costs and average pollutant removal costs for MCP in Option 6C* and in the preferred option for EU-wide MCP controls described in Annex 12.
Table A8.10: Emission reductions delivered and costs implied by an EU-wide legislative instrument to control air emissions from MCP
EU-wide MCP instrument MCP measures in Option 6C*
average average kiloton expenditure removal kiloton expenditure removal abated (M€) cost abated (M€) cost
(€/ton) (€/ton)
SO2 135 183 1400 79 104 1316
NOx 107 83 800 108 86 796
PM 45 116 2500 13 30 2308
Total 382 220
Note that the detailed analysis of Annex 12 is based on bottom-up information independent of the GAINS model-based analysis of the general Impact Assessment; these two approaches are complementary and give an indication of the uncertainties. Notwithstanding the uncertainties, the average removal costs are in good matching in the two cases. Pollution abatement expenditure is higher in the EU-wide instrument case for all pollutants except NOx. In summary, the preferred Option for a EU-wide MCP control instrument would entail for the MCP segment extra costs of the order of 162 M€/year, around 3% of the total expenditure entailed by the central case Option 6C*.
259
7.3. Updated BAT Conclusions under the IED
Emission standards for industrial sectors expressed as emission levels associated with Best Available Techniques are established in the BAT conclusions of the BREFs (BAT Reference documents) under the Industrial Emissions Directive (IED). The BREFs are periodically revised to reflect updated information on state of the art techniques for pollution control.
Sensitivity cases have been investigated to explore the impact of implementing packages of measures in some specific sectors at EU-wide level, as could be the case if the underlying techniques were defined as BAT in the relevant BAT conclusions. The sectors identified are: Cement & lime, glass, refineries, Chemicals, and solvent using activities; the measures, selected on the basis of clear cost-effectiveness demonstrated through the modelling in the majority of the Member States, are the following:
• In the cement & lime sector: further (stage 2) SO2 control; further (stage 2 and 3) NOx control; high-efficiency dedusters
• In the glass sector: further (stage 2) SO2 control; high-efficiency dedusters
• In the petroleum refining sector: further (stage 3) SO2 control; high-efficiency dedusters; use of low-sulphur fuel oil; leak detection and repair programmes; covers on oil-water separators; flaring
• In the chemicals sector: further (stage 3) SO2 control in sulphuric acid production; highefficiency
dedusters in fertilizers production; leak detection and repair programmes
• In the solvents sector: incineration in application of adhesives and in polystyrene processing; use of water-based preservatives in wood products; use of water-based coatings in leather coating
The results for packages of measures in the 6 sectors grouped in 3 clusters are the following:
Table A8.11: Costs implied by harmonised EU-wide measures in specific sectors covered by the IED
central Cement & Chemicals EU28, M€ case 6C* lime, glass Refineries and solvents power generation 500 -15 -68 -3
Domestic 1611 -3 64 0 Industrial combustion 610 85 29 0 Industrial processes 384 0 -2 2 Fuel extraction 6 0 0 0 Solvent use 63 0 -3 1 Road transport 0 0 0 0 Non-road sources 142 0 0 0
260
Agriculture 1356 -5 3 1
Total 4680 62 24 1
Additional costs compared to Option 6C* are:
• 85M€ in the cement& lime and in the glass sector, replacing measures for 15 M€ in the power sector, 3 M€ in the domestic sector, and 5 M€ in agriculture; the total balance is additional 62 M€, or 1,4 % of the 6C* costs
• 29M€ in the petroleum refining sector, replacing measures for 2 M€ in other industries and 3 M€ in solvent applications; the total balance is additional 24 M€, or 0,5 % of the 6C* costs
• 2M € in the chemicals sector and 1M € in solvent applications, replacing measures for 3M € in the power sector; the total balance is almost neutral (+1M€)
261
ANNEX 9 S ECTORIAL IMPACTS & C OMPETITIVENESS PROOFING
1. C ONTEXT AND DEFINITIONS
Competitiveness is a measure of an economy’s ability to provide its population with high and rising standards of living and high rates of employment on a sustainable basis. In this analysis the concern is to establish the extent to which the proposed policy will (or could) impact on the competitive position of firms within the EU compared with firms operating in the rest of the world. In some cases firms operate both within the EU and outside the EU and if the proposed policy were likely to encourage those firms to switch production outside of the EU that would be considered a weakening of the EU’s competitive position.
This annex complements the impact assessment accompanying the review of the Thematic Strategy on Air Pollution (TSAP review). One of the main objectives of the Review is to set a course that would –in the period beyond 2020- make further progress towards the resolution of problems associated with exposure to air pollution. This will require taking different actions depending on the sector involved and the kind of activity controlled, but in general would result in improving the air pollution standards of marketed products in their use phase (such as motor vehicles or heating appliances) or investing in pollution abatement equipment to reduce the amount of pollution generated by productive processes.
Investing in pollution abatement obviously represents a financial burden for the firms that have to make those investments, and different sectors may be more or less able to absorb that burden depending on the volume of investment needed, on the exposure to competition internationally (foreign producers of the same commodity) and also within the European market (domestic producers of potential substitutes).
2. S COPING OF THE COMPETITIVENESS ANALYSIS
The objectives proposed by the TSAP review are defined in terms of reduction of health and environmental impacts, and of emission reductions by Member State and by pollutant required to deliver the impact reductions; at this stage, it is up to the Member States to decide in which sectors to reduce emissions; however, the TSAP review also identifies the technical measures that would be most cost effective to reduce emissions in each MS and thereby suggests a cost-effective burden sharing by sector. The Review also suggests that some of the measures could be cost-effectively taken also as EU-wide source controls, which could deliver additional co-benefits in terms of administrative certainty and level playfield, but it will be ultimately up to the co-legislators to decide which share of emission reductions should be delivered by EU measures, and which by national action.
In conclusion, the technical measures and costs per sector identified by the Review are only one of the possible ways to meet the objectives, and at implementation may and will change. None the less, this annex discusses those measures that are determined to be the most costeffective way to meet the pollution reduction objectives of the Review.
The broad goal of this competitiveness analysis is to understand how meeting the proposed objectives of the TSAP review may affect individual economic sectors, whether specific sectors are particularly affected, and to identify possible mitigating measures that could reduce the burden on those sectors.
To do so, a sector-specific analysis is presented, where the cost-effective technical measures that may be taken in each sector to meet the proposed air quality objectives are presented, along with a brief analysis of the markets that supply pollution abatement technologies.
262
Implications of the direct costs of these proposed measures in terms of international trade flows and for SMEs are addressed as much as possible.
Pollution control measures, associated sectorial costs and impacts are discussed for three different levels of health and environmental improvements objectives in 2025; these levels correspond to policy options 6A, 6B and 6C of Chapter 6.
Broader economic impacts in terms of macro-economic aggregates are presented in Annex 7, to which this Annex is a complement.
3. S UPPLY OF ABATEMENT TECHNOLOGY
A brief analysis of the supply of abatement technology has been included in order to assess if there is the potential for a single supplier or single MS to benefit from enactment of the proposed regulation. If the regulation were found to favour one particular supply company, sector or member state this might be regarded as implying an (unintended) competition impact that would warrant further exploration.
Abatement technologies to reduce air emissions are manufactured by a range of companies ranging from the engineering or chemical companies to the energy specialist. For example, the energy giants Siemens (DE), Hitachi Europe GMBH (DE) and Alstom (FR) all provide multiple abatement techniques for various pollutants (NOx, SOx, dust and others). Other leading engineering European companies such as ABB (CH), Andritz (AT) and Fluor (UK) provide a wide range of abatement technologies such as SCR, FGD and electrostatic precipitators (ESP).
Some manufacturers are more specialised, that is the case of the Belgian Carmeuse, which is specialised in limestone product used for sulphur abatement and the Italian company Ansaldo which is specialised in in-furnace emission reduction systems (low NOx burners, air staging etc.). CMI (BE) is specialised in the design and construction of heat recovery steam generators. Similarly, Howden (UK) is a leading provider of rotary regenerative heat exchangers which are used for FGD and SCR. The British company Johnson Matthey is a leader in providing chemical catalysts. Finally, the Swiss Hug Engineers is a leader in diesel particulate filters and catalytic exhausts. All of these companies are large and have got multiple offices in and, for some, outside of the European Union. Whilst a majority of the abatement technologies manufacturers are large companies, there is a significant number of SMEs involved in the installations or the fitting of these technologies. Moreover, some more specific (specialist) technologies, particularly relevant for combustion engines, may be developed by smaller manufacturers.
This brief analysis supports the general conclusion that there is no one dominant supplier or dominant approach across the installations captured by the proposed regulation.
4. D EMAND FOR ABATEMENT TECHNOLOGIES : DETAILED MEASURES AND EXPENDITURE PER SUB - SECTOR
The type of additional pollution abatement measures identified through the modelling as the most cost-effective ones include:
• For SO2 abatement: controls on industrial process emissions; low sulphur coal/briquettes for small stoves; FGD/low S fuels for industrial furnaces; FGD for refineries and coke plants.
263
• For NOx abatement: SCR for cement plants; SCR/SNCR for mid-size boilers in power sector and industry; controls on some industrial process emissions
• For NH3 abatement: efficient application of urea fertilizer, or replacement by nitrate fertilizer; low nitrogen feed (pigs, dairy cows, poultry); low emission application of liquid and solid manures; closed storage of manures and new low emission housing (pigs, poultry)
• For primary PM control: modern biomass stoves with lower emissions and higher energy efficiency; reduction of agricultural waste burning; PM controls on some industrial processes
• For VOC control: modern biomass stoves with lower emissions and higher energy efficiency; further substitution with low solvent and water based products and processes; reduced agricultural waste burning
5. S ECTORIAL M ARKET A NALYSIS
Potentially significant competitiveness effects are assumed to be felt most significantly in sectors where international competition is greatest, specifically;
• Iron&steel
• Chemicals
• Petroleum refining
• Agriculture
• Other Energy intensive industries: e.g. glass sector
The GEM-E3 analysis (see Annex 7 for more details) has estimated the impacts in terms of trade flow for all sectors included in the analysis. The results are presented in the following table:
Table A9.1: EU28 import and export changes by sector on options 6A-6C
6A 6B 6C
Sectorial Imports in EU28 , % change
base health base health base health
Agriculture 0,01% 0,02% 0,07% 0,08% 0,28% 0,30%
Electric Goods 0,00% 0,01% 0,02% 0,03% 0,08% 0,10%
Transport equipment 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,03% 0,04% 0,07%
Petroleum Refining 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,03% 0,04% 0,06%
Ferrous and non-ferrous metals 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,03% 0,03% 0,06%
Chemical Products 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,03% 0,05% 0,07%
Other energy intensive 0,00% 0,01% 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,03%
Other Equipment Goods 0,00% 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,02% 0,04%
Consumer Goods Industries 0,00% -0,01% -0,02% 0,00% 0,01% 0,00%
264
Sectorial Exports in EU28, % change
base health base health base health
Agriculture -0,03% -0,02% -0,11% -0,09% -0,47% -0,44%
Electric Goods 0,00% 0,02% 0,02% 0,05% 0,10% 0,14%
Transport equipment 0,00% 0,02% 0,01% 0,04% 0,05% 0,10%
Petroleum Refining -0,02% -0,02% -0,07% -0,06% -0,20% -0,19%
Ferrous and non-ferrous metals 0,00% 0,02% -0,02% 0,01% -0,02% 0,03%
Chemical Products 0,00% 0,01% 0,00% 0,02% 0,00% 0,03%
Other energy intensive 0,00% 0,01% -0,01% 0,01% -0,03% -0,01%
Other Equipment Goods 0,00% 0,03% 0,02% 0,07% 0,09% 0,16%
Consumer Goods Industries 0,00% 0,01% -0,01% 0,01% -0,06% -0,03%
On options 6A-6C, imports to the EU of agricultural commodities would increase 0,01% to
0,3%, while exports would decrease -0,03 to-0,47%. Increased labour productivity due to health benefits ("health" case) could offset part of the export losses due to production cost increases due to the cost of compliance with air pollution reduction requirements. In terms of sectorial output (Table A9.2), on options 6A-6C the agricultural sector could lose between 0,01% and 0,20%. However, this result does not take into account the effects of increased crop yield due to ground-level ozone concentration reduction, which is estimated to be worth around €270M on option 6C, in the range of 0,1% of the total EU agricultural output, nor possible support schemes for the sector, discussed below in the sector-specific analysis. Similar conclusions can be drawn for the petroleum refining sector, although the magnitude of impacts –in particular on option 6C- is lower. The maximum output loss on option 6C would in this case be limited to -0,1%. None of the other sectors would incur substantial net losses, either because no significant effort is required of them on the policy options considered, or because they benefit from supplying pollution abatement equipment (chemical products as well as manufacturers of equipment).
Table A9.2: EU28 output changes by sector on options 6A-6C
6A 6B 6C
Sectorial output inpact in the EU28, % change
base health base health base health
Agriculture -0,01% 0,00% -0,06% -0,04% -0,22% -0,20%
Chemical Products 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,03% 0,03% 0,05%
Consumer Goods Industries 0,00% 0,00% -0,01% 0,00% -0,04% -0,01%
Electric Goods 0,00% 0,02% 0,03% 0,05% 0,10% 0,13%
Ferrous and non-ferrous 0,00% 0,01% -0,01% 0,02% 0,00% 0,03%
Petroleum Refining -0,01% 0,00% -0,03% -0,02% -0,10% -0,08%
Other energy intensive 0,00% 0,01% -0,01% 0,01% -0,02% 0,01%
Other Equipment Goods 0,00% 0,01% 0,02% 0,05% 0,06% 0,11%
Transport equipment 0,00% 0,01% 0,01% 0,04% 0,04% 0,09%
indicators calculated as relative changes do not differ significantly for 2025 and 2030. Exact figures reported are for 2025.
265 The market sectors affected are identified above; in the following sections, for each of them basic information on market structure including breakdown by firm size and is provided along with the overall and average gross value added and turnover typical of firms of each size group by number of employees, and impacts on specific sectors and sub-sectors are taken individually.
5.1. Metals (iron and steel; and non-ferrous metals)
Employment in the steel sector reached a peak of around 1 million in the EU during the 1970’s. Employment has declined to just over 400,000 in 2008 and the sector continues to face stiff competition from the new global steel producers of Eastern Asia, notably Korea and China. In spite of this stiff competition steel exports exceed imports. Basic data on the EU
steel industry follows 11 :
• EU share of global steel exports (top ten exporters) in 2010: 14 %.
• Biggest markets for EU steel exports in 2010 (in decreasing order of importance): Turkey, USA, Algeria, Switzerland, Russia, India.
• EU steel imports fell by about 50% from 40.2 million tonnes in 2008 to 20.7 million tonnes in 2009. In comparison, the steel exports from the EU only fell by 11% from 35 million tonnes in 2008 to 31 million tonnes in 2009, thus turning the EU steel trade balance to surplus after several years of deficit. In 2010 this surplus halved when imports grew by 30% to almost 27 million tonnes and exports increased only by 5% to 33.7 million tonnes in total.
The above data indicates that the average value of steel imported was around €670 per tonne (value divided by tonnage) while the value of steel exported was nearly 1,000 € per tonne. This is a strong indicator that the steel exported is of a higher quality (perhaps because of finishing or fabrication differences) than imported steel. Some of the decline in steel imports may be attributable to economic down turn although as can be seen exports held up comparatively well.
The following figures show steel imports and exports from 2006 projected forward to 2014. The EU has, since 2009 maintained a healthy trade surplus in steel but it is also apparent that it is a globally traded commodity that has the potential to be impacted by price. It is likely that in general steel producers in the EU are price takers and therefore have limited capacity for passing cost, although the EU does have specialist steel fabrication facilities and these may provide some shelter from non EU competition.
11 http://ec.europa.eu/trade/creating-opportunities/economic-sectors/industrial-goods/steel/#stats
266
Figure A9.1: EU27 imports of steel. Source: Eurofer, 2013 12
Figure A9.2: EU27 exports of steel. Source: Eurofer, 2013
Non-ferrous metals (principally Aluminium, Copper and Zinc) are important in manufacturing and production supply chains. The EU has limited raw material and mineral deposits, and the principal source is waste and scrap recycling. The EU has developed considerable specialism in these areas but the demand for such metals is greater than can be met through these routes. As a result the EU imports some €8 billion more than it exports
(2009 figures). Basic data on the EU non-ferrous metals sector follows 13 :
• Imports (2009): €34 billion / Exports (2009): €26 billion (trade balance: - €8 billion).
12 http://www.eurofer.org/index.php/eng/Issues-Positions/Economic-Development-Steel-Market
267
• The share of the non-ferrous metals sector in EU manufacturing value added is 1.37 %
(€23.4bn.).
• The share in employment is 1.0 % (334 800 people).
• Turnover of the sector was €139 billion (2.0 %).
Basic metals industries (iron & steel; and nonferrous
metals)
Yearly costs, total and per subsector, M €
natural hard total coke gas coal HFO Additional most cost-effective measures
Iron &Steel, low sulphur coal (0,6%); low sulphur fuel oil (0,6%); high combustion 6A 1,21 1,04 0,17 efficiency deduster
low sulphur coal (0,6%); low sulphur fuel oil (0,6%), high
6B 46,51 3,25 40,21 3,05 efficiency deduster, combustion modification, wet FGD
low sulphur coal (0,6%); low sulphur fuel oil (0,6%), high
6C 90,54 3,64 4,49 72,81 9,60 efficiency deduster, combustion modification, wet FGD
Iron & Steel, pig iron
blast furnace 6A 0,61 Stage 2 & 3 SO2 controls for process emissions
6B 4,38 Stage 3 SO2 controls for process emissions, EP (1 field)
Stage 3 SO2 controls for process emissions, EP (1 field), high
6C 6,28 efficiency deduster, good practices
I&S, Basic Oxygen
furnace 6A 0,22 EP (1 field)
6B 8,22 EP (1 field), high efficiency deduster
6C 9,45 high efficiency deduster
I&S, Cast iron 6A 0,02 EP (1 field)
6B 3,24 EP (1 field), high efficiency deduster, good practices
6C 7,40 high efficiency deduster, good practices
I&S, Coke oven 6A 1,22 Stage 3 SO2 controls for process emissions
Stage 1, 2 &3 SO2 controls for process emissions, high
6B 4,00 efficiency deduster, good practices
Stage 1 &3 SO2 controls for process emissions, high efficiency 6C 8,39 deduster, good practices
I&S, Sinter plant 6A 4,16 Stage 1 & 2 SO2 controls for process emissions
6B 17,81 Stage 2 & 3 SO2 controls for process emissions
6C 39,54 Stage 3 SO2 controls for process emissions
Non ferrous metals,
combustion 6A 0,63 0,63 high efficiency deduster
6B 2,61 0,20 2,41 high efficiency deduster
6C 6,83 2,08 4,75 high efficiency deduster
Non ferrous metals,
aluminium 6A 1,51 high efficiency deduster in primary aluminium
6B 1,52 high efficiency deduster in primary and secondary aluminium
6C 1,52 high efficiency deduster in primary and secondary aluminium
Non ferrous metals, 6A 1,43 Stage 2 SO2 controls for process emissions
268 other 6B 15,71 Stage 1, 2 & 3 SO2 controls for process emissions
6C 61,05 Stage 2 & 3 SO2 controls for process emissions
FGD: Flue Gas Desulphurisation; EP: Electrostatic Precipitator; combustion modification: limestone sorbent addition to solid fuel combustion.
Different stages of process emission controls are related to the production technologies, are site specific and depend onseveral parameters
including raw material quality. Stages 1-3 group these measures by progressively increasing costs.
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Manufacture of basic iron and steel and of 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+
C241 ferro-alloys Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises : : 353 140 170 196
Turnover 144.289,96 : : 1.945 10.646 129.285
Gross Value Added 22.109 219,72 304 312 1.463 19.793
Turnover per company 13,89 62,62 659,62
Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
The annual costs of the set of measures in the iron and steel industry identified as being the most cost-effective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
• In option 6A: 8 M €, equal to 0,006% of sectorial turnover and 0,04% of GVA
• In option 6B: 84 M€, equal to 0,06% of sectorial turnover and 0,4% of GVA
• In option 6C: 160 M€, equal to 0,11% of sectorial turnover and 0,72% of GVA
The largest share of this expenditure is for abatement of emissions in combustion units, in basic oxygen furnaces, and in sinter plants. Basic oxygen furnaces and sinter plants are generally embedded in large size industrial installations and are not expected to be a direct concern of SMEs. In all cases the additional required effort is less than 1% of GVA; the iron & steel sector also benefits from direct gains in terms of net output through demand for fabricated metal products as investment goods for pollution abatement.
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Manufacture of basic precious and other non 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+
C242 ferrous metals Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises 3.583 2.284 377 260 419 183
Turnover 103.109 1.900 : 4.577 31.313 63.204
Gross Value Added 16.347 600 : 633 4.054 10.398
Turnover per company 28,78 0,83 17,6 74,73 345,38
Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
The annual costs of the set of measures in the non-ferrous metals industry identified as being the most cost-effective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
In option 6A: 3,5 M €, equal to 0,003% of sectorial turnover and 0,02% of GVA
• In option 6B: 20 M€, equal to 0,02% of sectorial turnover and 0,12% of GVA
269
• In option 6C: 70 M€, equal to 0,07% of sectorial turnover and 0,44% of GVA
Most of this expenditure is for abatement of smelter process emissions (SO2). In all cases the additional required effort is less than 0,5% of GVA.
5.2. Chemicals
The chemicals sector is one of Europe's most competitive industrial sectors. Its work is focused on the manufacture of chemicals and the chemical transformation of materials into new substances or products. It covers a huge range of operations and outputs from basic organic and inorganic chemical products, through fertilizers, basic plastics, synthetics, rubbers, paints and varnishes to highly specialized consumer chemicals and polymers. Basic
data on the EU chemicals sector follows 14 :
• EU chemicals exports in 2009: €118 billion.
• EU chemicals imports in 2009: €75 billion.
• Biggest markets for EU chemical exports: US, Canada, Switzerland, Asia (China, India, Japan and ASEAN countries).
• Accounting for around 30% of the total world chemicals production, the EU is the world's most important producer of chemicals. In 2008 it produced €566 billion worth of chemicals. More than one third of world's top thirty chemical companies have their headquarters in the EU. The largest European producer of chemicals is Germany, which accounts for about 25% of EU production. Around 30,000 chemical companies employ a total staff of about 1.2 million people in the EU. Another three million employees work in sectors using output of the chemical industry and thus depend on its competitiveness.
• The EU trades more than 40% of all chemicals traded globally, compared with circa 15% for the NAFTA countries and circa 30% for Asia.
The figure below shows the growing importance of chemicals in the EU economy with both imports and exports growing progressively since 1999.
14 http://ec.europa.eu/trade/creating-opportunities/economic-sectors/industrial-goods/chemicals/
270
Figure A9.3: EU27 chemicals sector trade balance
Source: Cefic (2012): http://www.cefic.org/Documents/FactsAndFigures/2012/International
Trade/Facts-and-Figures-2012-Chapter-International-Trade.pdf
Chemical industry
Yearly costs, total and per subsector, M €
natural oil
total biomass gas products coal Additional most cost-effective measures
N - fertilizer production 6A 0,00
6B 2,54
6C 63,08 Combination of STRIP
Combustion in boilers 6A 0,33 0,14 0,00 0,07 0,12
Combustion modification on oil and gas industrial boilers and furnaces; High efficiency deduster; Low
6B 1,39 0,45 0,09 0,29 0,56 sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S);Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S)
Combustion modification on: oil and gas industrial boilers and furnaces, and solid fuels fired industrial
boilers and furnaces; High efficiency deduster;
Selective non-catalytic reduction on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; Good housekeeping:
industrial oil boilers; wet FGD; In-furnace control - 6C 20,27 7,54 2,21 2,34 8,18 limestone injection; Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S)
Other combustion Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S);
wet flue gases desulphurisation; High efficiency 6A 2,84 0,31 0,00 0,85 1,67 deduster; EP (1 field)
Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); wet FGD; In-furnace control - limestone injection;
Combustion modification on: oil and gas industrial
boilers and furnaces, and solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; Selective catalytic reduction on
solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; High
6B 7,27 0,88 0,14 2,23 4,03 efficiency deduster Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S);
wet FGD; In-furnace control - limestone injection;
6C 22,82 2,60 3,48 9,89 6,85 Combustion modification on: oil and gas industrial
271
boilers and furnaces, and solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective catalytic and noncatalytic
reduction on solid fuels fired industrial boilers
and furnaces; selective catalytic reduction on oil and gas industrial boilers and furnaces; Good
housekeeping: industrial oil boilers; High efficiency
deduster
Organic chemical industry
-
-downstream units 6A 0,26
6B 0,85 Leak detection and repair program, stage IV
6C 1,30 Leak detection and repair program, stage IV
Products incorporating
solvents 6A 0,01
6B 0,06 Basic emissions management techniques
6C 0,94 Basic emissions management techniques
Polystyrene processing 6% Pentane expandable beads (85%) and recycled EPS
6A 0,00 waste (15%)
6% Pentane expandable beads (85%) and recycled EPS 6B 0,17 waste (15%)
6% Pentane expandable beads (85%) and recycled EPS 6C 4,21 waste (15%); Combination of the above options
Ind. Process: Nitric acid 6A 0,00
6B 0,12
6C 2,87 Process emissions - stage 1 NOx control
Ind. Process: Sulfuric acid 6A 7,67 Process emissions - stage 2 SO2 control
6B 22,19 Process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 SO2 control
6C 58,80 Process emissions - stage 2 and 3 SO2 control
Combination of STRIP: stripping and absorption techniques in the chemical industry for N-fertilizers production
FGD: Flue Gas Desulphurisation; EP: Electrostatic Precipitator
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Manufacture of chemicals and 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+
C20 chemical products Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises 28.611 18.067 3.379 2.993 2.844 853
Turnover 490.000 14.682 12.142,36 28.547 121.000 313.629
Gross Value Added 111.000 2.667,27 2.912 7.164 26.000 72.257
Turnover per company 17,13 0,81 3,59 9,54 42,55 367,68 Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
The annual costs of the set of measures in the chemicals industry identified as being the most cost-effective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
In option 6A: 12 M €, equal to 0,002% of sectorial turnover and 0,003% of GVA
• In option 6B: 32 M€, equal to 0,01% of sectorial turnover and 0,03% of GVA
• In option 6C: 174 M€, equal to 0,04% of sectorial turnover and 0,16% of GVA
272 In all cases the additional required effort is less than about one quarter of a % point of GVA of the Chemical sector.
Additional expenditure for pollution control in combustion installations may raise to up to 20% of the figures above; additional expenditure for process emission abatement would mainly be for NOx control in Nitrogen fertiliser production, and SO2 control in sulphuric acid plants.
-
-N-Fertilizers production and trade
Mineral or INDICATORS/CODE chemical Fertilizers Fertilizers % over (M€) fertilizers, containing N, P containing N, P production
nitrogenous, n.e.c. and K, > 10% N and K, <= 10% N TOTAL value
Exports value 29,1 465,9 64,0 559,0 12
Imports value 4,7 398,2 116,8 519,7 11
Production value 1.200,0 2.537,5 1.017,1 4.754,5
Source: Generated from Eurostat database (2010 values used).
Additional costs for emission control could affect N-fertilizers trade fluxes due to the significant trade volumes (both imports and exports) of this commodity. In option 6C the additional control costs in this subsector would be of the order of 1% of the total production value.
-
-Sulphuric acid production and trade
% over INDICATORS/CODE (M€) Chlorosulphuric Sulphuric production
acid acid TOTAL value
Exports value 0,42 77,93 78,34 21
Imports value 2,88 7,03 9,90 3
Production value 4,00 365,17 369,17
Source: Generated from Eurostat database (2010 values used).
The EU is a net exporter of sulphuric acid (~18% of EU production value in 2010). There is a potential risk that additional costs for this sub sector (up to about 10% of the production value in option 6C) may be difficult to pass over to foreign traders.
5.3. Refining
The mineral oil and gas refinery industry is an important and strategic industry for the EU providing 42 % of the EU energy requirements and employing over 100 000 people.
Installations are broadly distributed around Europe. Refinery installations are typically very large and fully integrated plants, well connected to pipelines and infrastructure networks. Companies operating in the European refining sector can be categorised into 4 classes:
• So-called 'Majors' (Total, Shell, BP, Exxon) EU and non EU based companies operating worldwide in the exploration refining and distribution sectors
• Other EU based companies e.g. Repsol (ES), ENI (IT), Preem (SE), some of them historically stated-owned , operating on a more limited scope
273
• Smaller companies e.g, Motor Oil, Lyondell Basell, also operating on a more limited scope, mostly in refining activities (less upstream activities) which may be specialized (petrochemicals);
• National companies from non-EU countries operating European refinery plants, e.g. from crude-oil producers such as. Kuwait, Venezuela, Saudi Arabia and more recently Russia (Lukoil) or others like China (PetroChina)
There has been intense restructuring of the EU refining sector over the last 5 years with the emergence of new players from Asia and the Middle East. It is important to note that regions able to directly supply the European market with refined products (Russia, Middle East) are significantly increasing their refining capacities. Moreover, many EU refineries are 30 to 40 or more years old and therefore face financial and technological challenges to adapt to the current market situation due to their initial process configuration which is not flexible
enough. Basic data on the EU refinery sector follows 15 :
• After Asia, leading with 25 %, the largest refining regions are North America and Europe with close to 20 % of the global capacity each
• In 2010, the EU countries together operated 104 oil refineries, corresponding to a refining capacity of 778 million Tons/day
• In 2009 the volume of oil processed in EU refineries was 660 million Tons/day (= 85% of total capacity). There is a situation of structural over-capacity. Approximately 20% of capacity was unused in the EU. As a result, in the period 2011-2012, 10% of the capacity has been lost due to closures and restructuring of the refining sector. In Europe over the last 20 years there has been a slow but steady increase in unused refining capacity, partially due to the delocalisation of the industry, the relatively weak demand and the progressive specialisation of the demand on middle distillates directly importable from neighbouring areas. Recently, the EU, is the only region that has seen a fall in both demand (-0.9 %) and refining capacity (-2 %) in 2010. This has led to a temporary increase of the refining utilisation rate
• The transport sector and in particular road transport (being almost fully dependent on oil) remains the most energy consuming sector. In the EU, as much as 77.5% of goods are transported by road which implies that industry depends on refined products
• EU gasoline and diesel exports in 2010 were 95 million tonnes per year and imports 288 million tonnes per year.
• There are growing production/consumption imbalances at the level of individual products. In particular the shift over the last decade of motor fuels from gasoline to diesel has resulted in a production deficit of diesel (10%) and a surplus of gasoline (40%) in the EU
• The diesel deficit is covered to a large extent by imports from Russia (35% of diesel imports) and the gasoline is exported mainly to the USA (40%)
The figure below shows the trend of growing gasoline surplus and gasoil deficit.
15 Source: JRC- IPTS (2012)
274
Figure A9.4: EU’s foreign trade as a percentage of demand
Source: EUROPIA, 2011
Petroleum refining industry
Yearly costs, total and per subsector, M €
total Additional most cost-effective measures
Extraction, processing and distribution
of liquid fuels 6A 0,00
6B 0,00
Improved ignition systems on flares; Vapour balancing on tankers and loading
6C 6,58 facilities
Combustion 6A 28,55 Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S)
Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); Combustion modification on industrial boilers and
6B 50,16 furnaces
Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); wet FGD; high efficiency FGD; high efficiency deduster
6C 216,86 & good housekeeping; Combustion modification on industrial boilers and furnaces
Ind. Process: Crude oil & other
products - input to Petroleum 6A 3,45 Process emissions - stage 1 SO2 control; EP 1 field
refineries Process emissions - stage 1, 2 & 3 SO2 control; EP 1 & 2 field; Leak detection and 6B 52,78 repair program, stage II
6C 117,78 Process emissions - stage 2 & 3 SO2 control; high efficiency deduster
Steam cracking (ethylene and
propylene production) 6A 0,00 Leak detection and repair program, stage II
6B 0,07 Leak detection and repair program, stage II; COWS
6C 0,79 Leak detection and repair program, stage I and II; COWS
COWS: Covers on Oil/Water separators; FGD: Flue gas Desulphurisation; EP: Electrostatic Precipitator
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Manufacture of coke and refined petroleum 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+
C19 products Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises 1.120 623 147 113 117 97
Turnover 500.187 3.104 907 9.607 13.514 472.985
Gross Value Added 23.514 238,88 111 375 1.377 21.400
Turnover per company 446,60 4,98 6,17 85,02 115,50 4.876,14
275
Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
The annual costs of the set of measures in the refining industry identified as being the most cost-effective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
In option 6A: 32 M €, equal to 0,006% of sectorial turnover and 0,13% of GVA
• In option 6B: 103 M€, equal to 0,02% of sectorial turnover and 0,43% of GVA
• In option 6C: 342 M€, equal to 0,07% of sectorial turnover and 1,45% of GVA
The largest share of this expenditure is for abatement of emissions in combustion installations and in process installations treating crude oil and other products. Both are generally embedded in large size industrial installations and are not expected to be a direct concern of SMEs. Investment for process emission abatement would mainly be for SO2 control.
In options 6A and 6B the additional required effort is less than 0.5 % of GVA and in 6C is less than 1.3 %.
5.4. Agriculture and livestock rearing
The EU is the world's largest importer and exporter of agricultural products. Europe imports mostly basic agricultural commodities, but its exports are based on high quality farm products and other processed agricultural products. Basic data on the EU agriculture sector follows 16 :
• Total trade in agricultural products amounted to almost €153 billion in 2007, split
between EU imports from third countries of €77.4 billion and exports of €75.1 billion.
• Since the 1995 enlargement to EU15, imports have increased by 55% and exports by 68%.
• Over the years, the trade deficit has been reduced from more than €10 billion in 1988 to €5 billion in 1995 with an all-time low in 2005, when it amounted to only €27 million. In 2006, for the first time, the EU had a trade surplus of €4.5 billion but the trade balance went back again to negative in 2007 (€2.4 billion).
• The EU is the first importer from developing countries.
• In 2007, the 10 largest suppliers to the EU accounted for 55% of total imports of agricultural products into the EU. Brazil ranked first with €12 billion (16%) followed by the US (9%) and Argentina (8%).
• The EU's ten most important customers for agricultural products accounted for 56% of total exports. The US was the largest customer, absorbing some 19% of EU exports, followed by Russia and Switzerland (10% and 7% respectively).
16 http://ec.europa.eu/trade/creating-opportunities/economic-sectors/agriculture
276
As regards trade projections, the EU is expected to maintain its position as a net exporter of
pig and poultry meat and a net importer of beef and sheep meat. 17 Regardless that pig and
beef are under heavy competition from third countries and are expected to decline over the coming years, mostly due to high labour costs, but partly due to animal welfare and environmental forthcoming legislation and associated costs.
The figure below shows the growth of agriculture products imports and exports in the EU economy since 1989.
Figure A9.5: EU agricultural sector trade balance
In 2010, Agricultural output was 348.934 M€ and GVA at basic prices was 145.305 M€ (Eurostat data).
17 EC,,2012B: 'Prospects for Agricultural Markets and Income in the EU 2012-2022'.
277
Agriculture Yearly costs, total and per subsector, M €
Additional most cost-effective measures
Dairy cows - liquid (slurry) systems 6A 13,4 LNF, LNA and CS variously combined
6B 27,9 LNF, LNA and CS variously combined
6C 142,0 LNF, LNA, CS and SA variously combined
Dairy cows - solid systems 6A 2,6 LNF, LNA_high and LNA_low variously combined
6B 9,6 LNF, LNA_high and LNA_low variously combined
6C 19,4 LNF, LNA_high and LNA_low variously combined
Other cattle - liquid (slurry) systems 6A 8,1 Combination of CS and LNA
6B 11,8 Combination of CS and LNA
6C 81,1 Combination of CS and LNA
Pigs - liquid (slurry) systems 6A 18,4 LN, LNA CS and SA variously combined
6B 59,8 LN, LNA CS and SA variously combined
6C 544,8 LNF, LNA, CS, SA and BF variously combined; Biofiltration
Pigs - solid systems 6A 1,5 Combination of LNF and LNA_high
6B 4,0 LNF, LNA_high and LNA_low variously combined
6C 8,9 LNF, LNA_high and LNA_low variously combined
Other poultry 6A 1,6 LNF, LNA and SA variously combined
6B 17,9 LNF, LNA, SA and CS variously combined
6C 136,5 LNF, LNA, SA, CS and BF variously combined; Animal house adaption; Biofiltration
Laying hens 6A 0,5 LNF, LNA, SA and CS variously combined
6B 8,4 LNF, LNA, SA and CS variously combined
6C 45,6 LNF, LNA, SA, CS, BF variously combined; Biofiltration; Animal house adaption
Fertilizer use - urea 6A 0,0
6B 141,2 Urea substitution
6C 323,2 Urea substitution
Waste: Agricultural waste burning 6A 11,9 Reduced open burning of agricultural residues
6B 11,9 Reduced open burning of agricultural residues
6C 11,9 Reduced open burning of agricultural residues
LNA: Low ammonia application of manures
LNA_Low efficiency methods include slit injection, trailing shoe, slurry dilution, band spreading for liquid slurry, and incorporation of solid manure
by ploughing into the soil the day after application
LNA_High efficiency methods involve the immediate incorporation by ploughing within four hours after application, deep and shallow injection of
liquid manure and immediate incorporation by ploughing (within 12 hours after application) of solid manure
LNF: Low nitrogen feed
CS: Covered storage of manures
SA: Low emission housing
BF: Air purification
278 The annual costs of the set of measures in agriculture identified as being the most costeffective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
• In option 6A: 59 M €, equal to 0017,% of sectorial output and 0,04% of GVA
• In option 6B: 285 M€, equal to 0,08% of sectorial output and 0,2% of GVA
• In option 6C: 1292 M€, equal to 0,38% of sectorial output and 0,9% of GVA
It is estimated that for option 6C, the total extra costs for the Pigs liquid systems subsector will be 41% of the total expenditure (1292 M€). This will be partly compensated by increased income from larger crop yields due to lower concentrations of ground-level ozone.
The EU produces around 22 million tonnes of pork meat annually, making it the world’s second largest producer after China. Pig meat represents 21% of overall livestock production value. In several EU member states pig meat sector is the largest meat production sector, and
two thirds of pig meat production in the EU is produced in 6 countries 18 . Key sector
characteristics of EU27 are presented below:
Pigs
Number of holdings (1000s) 2,750 Number of pigs (1000s) 152,000
Production (1000s tonnes of meat) 12,000
Production (1000s heads) 164,000 Production value of meat (€ million) 31,000
Regular labour force 641,000
Source: Eurostat (2010 or most recent year).
In Option 6C, the additional expenditure for the Pig industry (liquid and solid systems) is estimated at 553,6 M€, representing 1.8% of the meat production value.
Regarding the type of enterprises affected, pig production is generally an intensive, indoor, large scale business with a relatively low level of variability in production systems. Both pig and poultry play an important role in mixed livestock small holdings throughout the EU, particularly in the EU 12, but this system represents little in terms of overall herd size and still much less in terms of contribution to overall production. Poultry production in the EU is highly industrialised, with around 60% of chickens reared intensively in large purpose-built facilities, operated by large companies.
In Option 6C, 25% of the total expenditure on ammonia control measures is for mineral fertilizers (urea substitution), affecting the arable crop sector. This sector can be divided into the following:
18 Germany, Spain, France; Poland, Denmark, the Netherlands
279
Production value at basic price (M€)
CEREALS (including seeds) 44.580,76
INDUSTRIAL CROPS 16.977,92
FORAGE PLANTS 25.041,00
VEGETABLES AND HORTICULTURAL PRODUCTS 49.855,58
POTATOES (including seeds) 10.102,68
FRUITS 23.345,36
WINE 12.948,57
OLIVE OIL 3.947,52
OTHER CROP PRODUCTS 2.076,99
CROP OUTPUT 188.875,38
Source: Eurostat database (2010 values).
Costs for urea substitution would be 141M€ in option 6B and 323 M€ in 6C, equal to 0,07% and 0,17% of crop output, respectively. 19% of the total expenditure for option 6C is related to cattle, including dairy cows (liquid and solid systems) and other cattle (liquid slurry systems).
In 2010, the total economic turnover for the EU dairy industry was €117 billion, representing about 13% of the turnover for the total food and drink industry in Europe (€900 billion), and
employing about 400,000 people, or 10%, of the 4 million working in the sector 19 .
Option 6C costs for dairy cows systems sum up 161 M€, representing 0.13% of EU dairy industry 2010 turnover.
Medium term prospects for milk and dairy products appear favourable due to the continuing expansion of world demand. Global population and economic growth, and increasing preference for dairy products are expected to be the main drivers, fuelling EU exports and sustaining commodity prices.
Milk production in the EU is not as competitive as in some other parts of the world, due to the cost of milk quotas, animal welfare regulations and relatively high costs of land, buildings
and labour 20 . However, fresh milk products are mainly produced and consumed locally due to
their short shelf-life and are therefore not significantly exposed to EU-external trade.
Regarding Beef industry, in 2011 the total indigenous production of beef in the EU-27 was 8,371 thousand tonnes (13% of the world beef and veal production); 350 thousand tonnes of
production was exported 21 . In 2010, the total economic turnover was around €90 billion,
representing about 10% of the turnover for the total food and drink industry in Europe (€900 billion).
19 IUF Dairy Industry Research, http://cms.iuf.org/sites/cms.iuf.org/files/European%20Union%20Dairy%20Industry.pdf
20 'Competitiveness of the EU dairy industry' (LEI Wageningen UR, 2009).
21 EC, 2011: ‘Prospects for Agricultural Markets and Income in the EU 2011-2020’.
280
In Option 6C, expenditure in the sector "other cattle different from dairy cows" totals 81M€, or 0.09% of beef industry turnover for 2010.
Historically, the EU has been a major beef exporter. However, the year 2003 marked the shift
in the EU beef trade balance, with beef and veal imports exceeding exports to date 22 , due to
reduced production and policy changes. While the trade balance was strengthened in 2010 and 2011, production has been declining steadily. The main underlying reason is that EU beef production is currently less competitive compared with third countries (primarily the MERCOSUR group), due to relatively more expensive feed and labour conditions, smaller
livestock supplies, high levels of bio- security regulation, and smaller economies of scale 23 .
In future, the competitive disadvantage of EU beef producers is likely to continue, albeit some competitiveness factors such as labour cost may even out.
In option 6C, additional expenditure in the poultry industry including laying hens and other poultry totals 182 M€, 14% of total additional ammonia control costs, representing 0,73% of the sector output.
The EU produces around 11 million tonnes of poultry meat annually and well over 35 billion eggs (Eurostat – figure is a minimum value as it excludes countries expected to be important producers, such as Italy and the UK). In value terms, poultry meat represents 13% of livestock production value, and eggs 4%. Poultry meat is the second most popular meat in the
EU, representing 25% of EU meat consumption overall. 24 Key sector characteristics are
presented in A9.3.
Table A9.3: Key characteristics of EU27 poultry industry (2010 or most recent prior to 2010 where not available). Source: Eurostat (except where specified in the notes)
Broilers Laying hens Total
Number of holdings (1000s) 2,200 4,100 4,800 (1)
Number of hens (1000s) 876,000 510,000 1,620,000 (2)
Production (1000s tonnes of >> 6,100 (3) >> 3,600 (4) n/a
meat/eggs)
~ 11,000 (5) ~ 6,900 (6)
Production (1000s heads/eggs) >> 4,360,000 (3) >> 35,000,000 (4) n/a
Production value of meat/eggs 17,000 7,700 24,700 (€ million)
Regular labour force (specialist n/a n/a 1,000,000
poultry) (7)
Notes: (1) Total number of holdings is lower than the sum of its components as many holdings have both broilers and laying hens. (2) The total number of hens is higher than the sum of broilers and laying hens as there are also poultry classified as “other”. (3) Meat production given as minimum values as Eurostat only has such data for 10-12 Members States. (4) Eggs
22 European Commission, DG Agriculture and rural development. Webpage: Beef and Veal.
http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/markets/beef/index_en.htm 23 European Commission, (2007), DG Enterprise and Industry, 'Competitiveness of the European Food
Industry: An Economic and Legal Assessment 2007'. (EC, 2006) 24 Sources: 'Evaluation of the livestock sector's contribution to the EU greenhouse gas emissions (GGELS), Final
report' (JRC,2010); 'Prospects for agricultural markets and income in the EU 2011–2020' (EC, 2011); 'Egg production in the EU' (Compassion in World Farming, 2012).
281
production given as minimum values as Eurostat data excludes countries expected to be important producers, such as Italy and the UK. (5) JRC (2010) estimate. (6) http://www.compassionlebensmittelwirtschaft.de/wpcontent/uploads/2012/05/Info-1-Egg-production-in-the-EU.pdf.pdf (7) It is likely that the actual labour force will be higher than this, as non-specialists are likely to be employed in poultry rearing, slaughter etc.
The EU is a net exporter of poultry meat, with over a quarter of production exported. EU exports increased significantly in the period 2008-2011, due to increasing demand from Asia, Africa and the Middle-East, combined with a relatively weak Euro. Exports are expected to gradually decrease again up to 2020, as the Euro strengthens. Main exports markets include Asia, Africa and the Middle-East, while sources of imports are Brazil and with Thailand being an increasingly important source of imports. The EU is also a net exporter of eggs
(188,000 tonnes exported and 35,000 imported in 2009 25 ); EU imports are limited by
Salmonella legislation and imports are thus only allowed from Switzerland, Norway and
Croatia 26 .
Poultry production in the EU is highly industrialised, with around 60% of chickens reared intensively in large purpose-built facilities, operated by large companies that control all stages of production – breeding, hatching, feedstuff manufacture, and meat delivery. Some 40% are produced by independent farmers, generally under contract to a processor. The situation for laying hens is similar, with 60% of laying hen population reared in farms with > 40,000 heads (despite such farms making up only 0.1% of all farms).
In terms of contributions to emission reductions and of economic impacts on farms of different sizes, the following table presents a breakdown of ammonia emission reducitons in
options 6A, 6B and 6C. Farm sizes are grouped by livestock units (LSU 27 ), and in all cases it
is assumed that very small farms of less than 15 LSU are exempted from all measures.
NH3 reductions
6A 15-50 LSU 50-500 LSU >500 LSU
Cattle 18,20% 62,40% 19,40%
Pigs 4,70% 5,30% 90,00%
Poultry 0,10% 1,50% 98,40%
6B 15-50 LSU 50-500 LSU >500 LSU
Cattle 17,00% 68,70% 14,30%
Pigs 4,30% 18,50% 77,20%
Poultry 0,10% 1,30% 98,60%
6C 15-50 LSU 50-500 LSU >500 LSU
Cattle 17,50% 71,20% 11,30%
Pigs 5,80% 36,50% 57,70%
Poultry 1,30% 17,80% 80,90%
In Option 6C, small farms between 15 and 50 LSU cost-effectively deliver around 20% of ammonia emission reductions from cattle farming, 9% of the reductions from pig farming, and 2,5% from poultry farms; the cost shares borne by farms of the same sizes are
25 Compassion in World Farming, 2012
26 EUWEP, 2011.
27 Following Eurostat definition
282
comparable to the emission reduction shares. Although the implementation of specific measures remains under the responsibility of the Member States, this analysis shows that poultry farms below 50 LSU can be exempted without significantly compromising the environmental objectives of Option 6C (about 1 KT more ammonia would be emitted). However, for pigs and especially cattle, the share of emission reductions from farms below 50 LSU is larger, representing ammonia emission reductions of about 15 and 48 KT respectively, with associated emission control costs estimated at around 30 and 45 M€/year. Given that the potential for cost-effective ammonia reduction measures is very substantial in this segment, adequate support measures can be channelled through the EU rural development policy, provided that the Member States themselves give priority to air pollution.
5.5. Power sector
The European electricity mix is becoming more diverse: by 2020 renewable electricity is set to make up 35% of European power production, with fossil fuel fired plants increasingly operating as back-up. This step change implies a need for significant investment in power generation and transport capacity – and a coherent policy framework to support such investment and the necessary innovation.
Thermal generation - coal, gas and nuclear - today represents the backbone of the European power system. Challenges to thermal generation include climate change, supply security and volatile fossil fuel prices. Thermal generators also have specific features that are becoming more important as the share of variable (i.e. not constantly available) renewables grows.
Basic data on the EU power sector follows 28 :
• European electricity sector gathers 3.500 companies and 2.000 distribution companies, with 800.000 employees.
• European electricity capacity s 900 GW and the annual generation 3.800 TWh
• After a decade of growth and a partial recovery in 2010 after the economic crisis of 2009, electricity demand fell again in 2011 as the European economy struggled with the prolonged sovereign debt crisis (Figure A9.7)
• The EU’s renewables capacity increased yet again in 2011, reaching 34% of total installed capacity. Renewables progressively move to the centre of electricity systems and both capacity and generation are expected to be substantially higher in 2020 than today (Figure A9.8). By 2020 45% of all power plants will be renewable based, generating some 31% of Europe’s electricity. Low-carbon electricity from nuclear and renewables will account for 56% of all electricity generated.
28 Source: EURELECTRIC, 2012
283
Figure A9.6: Electricity demand (including network losses) in the EU 27, 2000-2011
Source: EURELECTRIC, 2012
284
Figure A9.7: Evolution of installed capacity in the EU-27
Source: EURELECTRIC, 2012
Power sector
Yearly Costs, total and per subsector, M €
Total Coal Biomass Natural Oil Waste Additional most cost-effective gas (incl. product fuel, Measures
other s renewable
gases)
Other Energy 6A 1,05 1,03 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,02 Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); Low sulphur coal (0.6
Sector – %S); Combustion modification on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; EP (1 field)
combustion
6B 3,87 3,84 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,03 Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); wet FGD; In-furnace
control - limestone injection; Low sulphur coal (0.6
%S); EP1 (field); Combustion modification on: oil and
gas, and solid fuels fired industrial boilers and
furnaces boilers and furnaces; Selective catalytic
reduction on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and
furnaces; High efficiency deduster
6C 32,04 8,62 0,06 9,96 13,35 0,06 Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); wet FGD; In-furnace
control - limestone injection; Low sulphur coal (0.6
%S); Combustion modification on oil and gas, and
solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces;
Selective non-catalytic reduction on oil and gas, and
on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces;
Selective catalytic reduction on solid fuels fired
industrial boilers and furnaces; High efficiency
deduster; Good housekeeping: industrial oil boilers
Power & 6A 0,04 - - 0,00 0,04 - Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); Euro 4, 5 and 6; Stage 5
district heat and 2 control
plants with 6B 0,58 - - 0,00 0,58 - Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); Euro 4, 5 and 6; Stage 5 internal and 3A control
combustion 6C 1,29 - - 0,00 1,29 - Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); Euro 5 and 6; Stage 5
engines control
285
Power & 6A 11,84 11,8 - - - - Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Combustion modification
district heat 4 on existing brown coal power plants; High efficiency deduster
plants, existing;
coal/lignite 6B 34,38 34,3 - - - - Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); wet FGD; Combustion
fired, large 8 modification on existing hard and brown coal power plants; High efficiency deduster
units ( > 50
MW th ) 6C 51,24 51,2 - - - - Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); wet FGD; Combustion
4 modification on existing hard and brown coal power plants; Selective catalytic reduction on existing hard
coal power plants; High efficiency deduster
Power & 6A 0,81 - 0,81 0,00 0,00 0,00 Combustion modification on existing oil and gas
district heat power plants; EP (1 field)
plants existing, 6B 16,90 - 16,40 0,00 0,50 0,00 Combustion modification on existing hard coal, and non-coal; for oil and power plants; wet FGD; High efficiency
GAS - boilers deduster
6C 39,39 - 32,63 4,39 2,29 0,08 Wet FGD; Combustion modification on existing hard
coal and oil and gas power plants; High efficiency
deduster; Good housekeeping: industrial oil boilers
Power & 6A 0,36 0,36 - - - - Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Combustion modification
district heat on existing brown coal power plants; High efficiency deduster
plants, existing;
coal/lignite 6B 1,27 1,27 - - - - Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); wet FGD; Combustion
fired, small modification on existing brown coal power plants; High efficiency deduster
units ( < 50
MW th ) 6C 4,15 4,15 - - - - Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); wet FGD; Combustion modification on existing brown coal power plants;
High efficiency deduster
Power & 6A 1,77 - 1,77 - 0,00 0,00 EP (1 field)
district heat
6B
plants new, 17,75 - 17,75 - 0,00 0,00 High efficiency deduster
non-coal; for
6C 57,73 - 41,58 - 1,18 14,97 Selective non-catalytic reduction on other biomass GAS - turbines and waste fuels for new powerplants; Selective
catalytic reduction on new oil and gas power plants;
High efficiency deduster
Power & 6A 0,13 0,13 - - - - Wet FGD
district heat
6B
plants, new; 1,65 1,65 - - - - Wet FGD; High efficiency FGD; High efficiency deduster
coal/lignite
6C
fired, large 78,17 78,1 - - - - Wet FGD; High efficiency FGD; Selective catalytic reduction on new hard and brown coal power plants;
units ( > 50 7 High efficiency deduster
MW th )
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Electric power generation, transmission and 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+
D351 distribution Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises 45.037 41.883 708 704 697 441
Turnover 951.226 64.466 18.224 49.911 169.011 648.105
Gross Value Added 174.597 11.291 2.589 5.034 16.691 138.593
Turnover per company 21,12 1,54 25,74 70,90 242,48 1469,63 Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
286
As can be seen from the above table the turnover of the largest firms in electric power generation is far higher than for the other sectors / uses identified, this reflects the concentration of the industry in a small number of substantial operators and a larger number of small niche operators (renewables). The former means that additional investment entailed by the policy would not likely affect SMEs.
The annual costs of the set of measures in the power sector identified as being the most costeffective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
• In option 6A: 16 M €, equal to 0,002% of sectorial turnover and 0,01% of GVA
• In option 6B: 76 M€, equal to 0,01% of sectorial turnover and 0,04% of GVA
• In option 6C: 264 M€, equal to 0,03% of sectorial turnover and 0,15% of GVA
The largest proportion of this expenditure is for emissions abatement in new large units (> 50 MWth) of power and district heat plants coal/lignite fired, and in non-coal new power and district heat plants for gas turbines. Both are generally large size industrial installations and are not expected to be a direct concern of SMEs. In all cases the additional required effort is less than 0,2 % of GVA.
5.6. Other energy intensive industries
These include the pulp and paper sector, the cement sector, the lime sector, and the glass
sector. Basic data on the EU energy intensive industries follows 29 :
5.6.1. Pulp and paper sector
• According to the latest structural data available, there were 19,377 firms employing 715,000 people in the sector in 2006.
• In 2006, "pulp manufacturing" represented 5% of added value and 2% of employment, "paper manufacturing" 39% and 29% and "articles of paper and paperboard" 56% and 69% respectively
• Apart from a slight fall in 2005, production in the "pulp, paper and paper products" sector increased steadily by more than 12% between 2002 and 2007. However, in 2008, production was 2.5% lower than in 2007, and turnover in 2008 was almost the same as in 2007, marking a change in the trend from previous years. Employment fell by 15% between 2000 and 2008.
• The EU is a net exporter of paper and paper articles, with a trade surplus of €11.5 billion
in 2008. It is a net importer of pulp, with a trade deficit of €3.5 billion in the same year.
• In 2007, the EU accounted for 21.3% of the world pulp production of 194.2 Mt. but remains a net importer, mostly from the Americas. 80% of the pulp imported into the EU
29 Sources: http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/sectors/wood-paper-printing/index_en.htm http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/sectors/metals-minerals/non-metallic-mineral-products/index_en.htm
287
comes from Brazil, the US, Canada and Chile. Pulp producers in the southern hemisphere are playing an ever-increasing role, due to lower material and labour costs, and this is leading to a situation in which the pulp and paper companies, including European ones, are investing in these countries
• For paper, the EU was the world's largest producer in 2007, providing 26% of the global total of 394 Mt. The main destinations for EU paper exports and paper articles are Russia, the US and Switzerland, which account for 12%, 10% and 9.5% of total EU27 exports respectively. Imports from Asia are developing rapidly, and in 2008 China became the third EU supplier for paper and paper articles, following Switzerland and the US. Imports from China have risen by 76% since 2005
5.6.2. Cement sector
The majority of EU cement producers are operating on a global level, with the USA as a major trading partner. Depending entirely on the demand of the building and civil engineering requirements, the cement industry provides direct employment in local areas and through a wide network of indirect jobs and activities related to the main manufacturing process. Environmental concerns are of paramount importance for the sector, and innovation includes the use of wastes as alternative raw materials and fuels.
• Output in the cement industry has been climbing steadily in recent years, up 23% between 1998 and 2007. Total tonnage produced in EU 27 in 2006 amounted to just over 267.1 million tonnes, with a value of € 19 billion. This represented approximately half of one per cent of total value added and a quarter of one per cent of numbers employed in total manufacturing
• Employment has been decreasing steadily over recent years, and in 2006, it is estimated that there were 56.500 direct jobs (EU 27)
• In 2007, 3% of production was exported outside the EU, whilst non-EU 27 imports supplied 7% of consumption
• The main destination for EU 27 cement and clinker exports is traditionally the USA, because of its unstable domestic demand. Imports, three-quarters of which are clinker, come mainly from far eastern Asian countries, like China, Thailand, and the Philippines
• Where European cement producers have identified demand for cement in non-EU countries, they have generally invested in manufacturing sites in those countries. As such, EU companies now own almost 60% of US production capacity, and have significant production facilities in the rest of the world
5.6.3. Lime sector
The EU lime industry is characterised by the existence of several big EU producers operating on an international stage, giving them access to global best practice and technology, and markets for a wide range of applications. Lime production technology and efficiency have evolved over several thousand years, to the extent that they represent the best possible in terms of environmental performance. Production of lime fell at the end of the 1980s as a
288
result of changes in patterns of consumption, specifically the biggest consumer, the steel industry. Production started to grow again in the mid-1990s with the growing use of environmental applications, such as water, sludge, soil, acid gas, and disinfection treatments. Apart from these two applications, lime is also used in construction and clay soil stabilisation, chemicals, paper, food, feed, and healthcare, etc.
• In EU 27 in 2006, production was estimated at 28 million tonnes, roughly 12% of the
227 million tonnes produced worldwide. This was worth a value of some € 2.5 billions
• Numbers employed are estimated at 11.000
• Lime is a heavy product with a relatively low selling price, so transport costs dictate over what distance it can normally be transported on a regular basis under viable conditions. Only a very small percentage of total production is exported, and this is mainly to neighbouring countries. Where the biggest producer has identified potential markets, it has usually taken the decision to invest in production capacity in those markets
5.6.4. Glass sector
The glass industry is characterised by the existence of several large EU-based companies competing on world markets, economies of scale, the quality of its products, its capacity for technological innovation, and its skilled labour force. The European glass industry is made up of a number of distinct sectors, manufacturing products for a wide range of uses. The sectors are container glass which accounts for about 60% of output, flat glass (30%), and others.
• Total production in EU27 in 2007 is estimated to have reached 37.55 million tonnes, up on the 36.43 million tonnes produced in 2006. This represented about 30% of total world glass production. It was worth in the region of €39 billion (about €38.5 billion in 2006), representing about 32% of the value of total world production
• Numbers employed in 2006 is estimated at just under 237.000
• 70% of all glass products are produced in just 5 member States: Germany, France, Italy, Spain, and the UK
• About 80% of output is traded with other Member States. The figure for extra-EU trade is much lower, and EU exports were double the tonnage of imports into the EU in 2003. By 2007, this had changed to a situation whereby the EU (27) was a net importer, due principally to an increase of imports from outside the EU. There are many countries which the EU glass industry sees as having trading potential where there are tariff barriers.
Non-metallic minerals and pulp and paper sectors
Yearly costs, total and per subsector, M €
Natural Oil
total Coal Biomass gas products Additional most cost-effective Measures
Paper and 6A 0,01 0 0 0 0,01 Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S)
289
pulp Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); combustion modification on solid production, 6B 0,14 0 0,01 0 0,13 fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces combustion Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); combustion modification: on solid
fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces and on oil and gas industrial boilers and furnaces; high efficiency deduster; EP (1
6C 8,81 2,33 5,73 0,32 0,43 field); wet FGD
Paper and Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); wet pulp 6A 0,3 0,18 0,04 0 0,08 FGD; EP (1 field); high efficiency deduster production, Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); wet other FGD; In-furnace control - limestone injection; high efficiency combustion deduster; EP (1 field); combustion modification on oil and gas and
on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective catalytic reduction on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and
6B 1,68 0,62 0,49 0 0,57 furnaces Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Low sulphur fuel oil (0.6 %S); high efficiency deduster; EP; good housekeeping: industrial oil boilers; wet FGD; in-furnace control - limestone injection; combustion modification: on oil and gas and on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective catalytyc and non-catalytic reduction on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective
6C 6,17 1,36 1,85 0,7 2,26 catalytic reduction on oil and gas industrial boilers and furnaces
Paper and
pulp mills 6A 1,09 Process emissions - stage 1 and 2 SO2 control 6B 7,01 Process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 SO2 control
6C 17,4 Process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 SO2 control
Cement 6A 0,24 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,24
combustion Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); combustion modification on solid fuels
6B 1,04 0,02 0,00 0,00 1,02 fired industrial boilers and furnaces Low sulphur diesel oil - stage 2 (0.045 % S); wet FGD; in-furnace control - limestone injection; High efficiency deduster; combustion modification on: oil and gas and on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective catalytic and non-catalytic reduction
6C 15,88 2,96 0,19 0,30 12,43 on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces
Cement 6A 0,33 Process emissions - stage 2 SO2 control production Process emissions - stage 1 and 2 NOx control; high efficiency
6B 40,84 deduster; process emissions - stage 1 and 2 SO2 control
Process emissions - stage 2 and 3 NOx control; high efficiency
6C 235,16 deduster; process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 SO2 control
Glass 6A 0,10 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,10 combustion Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Combustion modification on solid fuels
6B 0,46 0,01 0,00 0,00 0,45 fired industrial boilers and furnaces Low sulphur diesel oil - stage 2 (0.045 % S); wet FGD; in-furnace control - limestone injection; high efficiency deduster; combustion modification on: oil and gas and on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective catalytic and non-catalytic reduction
6C 6,95 1,29 0,09 0,13 5,44 on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces
Glass 6A 1,25 High efficiency deduster; EP (1 field) production High efficiency deduster; process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 SO2
6B 7,01 control High efficiency deduster; process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 SO2
6C 25,21 control
Lime 6A 0,09 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,09 combustion Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); combustion modification on solid fuels
6B 0,38 0,01 0,00 0,00 0,38 fired industrial boilers and furnaces Low sulphur diesel oil - stage 2 (0.045 % S); wet FGD; in-furnace control - limestone injection; High efficiency deduster; combustion modification on: oil and gas and on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective catalytic and non-catalytic reduction
6C 5,81 1,08 0,07 0,11 4,55 on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces
Lime
production 6A 2,81 Process emissions - stage 1 and 2 SO2 control
Process emissions - stage 2 NOx control; process emissions - stage 6B 10,3 1 and 2 SO2 control
Process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 NOx control; high efficiency 6C 42,49 deduster; process emissions - stage 1, 2 and 3 SO2 control
Other 6A 0,08 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,08 combustion Low sulphur coal (0.6 %S); Combustion modification on solid fuels
6B 0,37 0,01 0,00 0,00 0,36 fired industrial boilers and furnaces Low sulphur diesel oil - stage 2 (0.045 % S); wet FGD; in-furnace control - limestone injection; High efficiency deduster; combustion modification on: oil and gas and on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces; selective catalytic and non-catalytic reduction
6C 5,60 1,04 0,07 0,11 4,38 on solid fuels fired industrial boilers and furnaces
Other 6A 4,74 High efficiency deduster; EP (1 field)
(gypsum, 6B 10,91 High efficiency deduster; EP (1 field)
PVC…) High efficiency deduster; EP (1 field); stripping and vent gas production 6C 14,4 treatment
FGD: Flue Gas Desulphurisation; EP: Electrostatic Precipitator
290
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Manufacture of pulp, 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+ C171 paper and paperboard Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises : 1.228 : 200 : 209
Turnover 80.000 : 506,51 1.855,53 13.791,76 60.617,98
Gross Value Added : : 124,94 415,94 2.937,7 12.989,51
Turnover per company 9,28 290,04 Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
The annual costs of the set of measures in the pulp and paper industry identified as being the most cost-effective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
• In option 6A: 1 M €, equal to 0,002% of sectorial turnover and 0,009% of GVA
• In option 6B: 9 M€, equal to 0,01% of sectorial turnover and 0,05% of GVA
• In option 6C: 32 M€, equal to 0,04% of sectorial turnover and 0,2% of GVA
The percentages above are calculated without taking into account turnover and GVA of companies with less than 10 employees.
The pulp manufacturing industry consists for the most part of large and very large firms, often multi-nationals, which are frequently involved with paper operations. They are very capital-intensive industries, as a new state-of-the-art pulp mill costs around €1 billion, or even more if it is part of a paper mill. Paper mills for "commodity grades" of paper, i.e. those intended for further cutting into sheets or rolls or subsequent conversion into products, are most often also large or very large and also quite capital-intensive, especially if there are several paper machines on one site. Plants producing speciality grades may be smaller. Conversely, most converting mills, i.e. those producing usable paper products, are SMEs.
None of the cases required additional effort bigger than 0.2% of the GVA.
The largest share of this expenditure is for the control of SO2 process emissions in paper and pulp mills. Regarding paper and pulp production, the higher costs are in combustion of biomass.
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Manufacture of cement, lime and 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+
C235 plaster Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises : : 103 102 118 80
Turnover 21.373 448 301 1.030 4.401 15.193
Gross Value Added 7.877 88,5 79 281 1.461 5.967
Turnover per company 2,92 10,10 37,30 189,92 Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
291
The annual costs of the set of measures in the cement, lime and plaster industry identified as being the most cost-effective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
• In option 6A: 8 M €, equal to 0,04% of sectorial turnover and 0,1% of GVA
• In option 6B: 63 M€, equal to 0,3% of sectorial turnover and 0,8% of GVA
• In option 6C: 313 M€, equal to 1,5% of sectorial turnover and 4% of GVA
Most of this expenditure belongs to the cement production industry for abatement measures of NOx and SO2 emissions (in case A3 75% of the expenditure is on this sector).
-
-Cement production and trade
INDICATORS/CODE Other % over
(M€) Cement Portland hydraulic production clinker cement cements TOTAL value
Exports value 189,2 383,6 71,5 644,3 5
Imports value 146,7 173,3 31,8 351,8 2
Production value 694,9 11.579,3 1.931,8 14.205,9 Source: Generated from Eurostat database (2010 values used).
The table above shows that cement imports represents only 2% of the total cement production value; this indicates that the European cement sector has sufficient headroom to absorb additional pollution control measures, even if option 6C may require the commitment of substantial additional resources from this sector.
292
CODE NACE_R2/SIZE_EMP By size of company
Manufacture of glass 0-9 10-19 20 -49 50 -249 250+ C231 and glass products Total employees employees employees employees employees
Number of enterprises : : 1.289 882 713 230
Turnover : : 1.502 2.962 11.115 26.839
Gross Value Added : 667 : 1.000 3.499 9.339
Turnover per company 1,17 3,36 15,59 116,69 Source: Generated from Eurostat database query on turnover and number of enterprises (2010 values used).
The annual costs of the set of measures in the glass industry identified as being the most costeffective under the policy scenarios analysed is the following:
• In option 6A: 1,4 M €, equal to 0,003% of sectorial turnover and 0,01% of GVA
• In option 6B: 7,5 M€, equal to 0,02% of sectorial turnover and 0,05% of GVA
• In option 6C: 32 M€, equal to 0,08% of sectorial turnover and 0,2% of GVA
The majority of this expenditure is for the control of SO2 process emissions in glass production. None of the cases required additional effort bigger than 0.2% of the GVA.
6. C ONCLUSIONS
Potential impacts on competitiveness concentrate in sectors that -being more exposed to international competition- will have more difficulty passing through additional costs to their markets, such as refineries, chemicals, iron & steel and agriculture. .It is likely that at least a sub set of these users will have difficulty in passing costs through to their current markets. Of these sectors, the most significantly affected would be agriculture and petroleum refining; in all these cases, however, the additional resources that would be committed under the policy options considered would be below or in the order of the 1% threshold of Gross Value Added, indicating headroom to absorb the additional costs.
Considering the type of installations and abatement measures involved, impacts on SMEs are considered significant for agricultural measures and for measures in medium-scale combustion plants.
Possible mitigation could focus on actions targeted at the specific sectors most likely to face international competition and measures for reducing impacts on SMEs. Applying exemptions/derogations to those sectors/uses facing the greatest international competition could be considered.
SMEs could be affected in the medium combustion plants (MCP) segment and in agriculture. SME impacts related to MCP are taken in Annex 12. For agriculture, all farms below the 15 animal heads are assumed to be exempted from further ammonia control measures. This threshold could be extended to poultry farms below 50 heads without significantly compromising the environment. For cattle farms below 50 heads, the earmarking by the Member States of appropriate resources under the rural development policy could provide the
293
sector with adequate financing. For pig farms below 50 heads, both options (exemptions or financing through the rural development policy) could be considered by the Member States.
ANNEX 10 C ONTROLLING METHANE EMISSIONS
In 2005, agricultural activities (mainly livestock farming) emitted almost half of the methane (CH 4 ) emissions in the EU-28. Another one third of emissions originated from waste treatment (from solid waste disposal and wastewater treatment), and 14% from fuel extraction and distribution (i.e., coal mining and distribution of natural gas).
1. P ROJECTED METHANE EMISSIONS ASSUMING NO CHANGE TO CURRENT POLICIES
Methane emissions in the EU are expected to decline by more than 20% in 2025 compared to 2005 due to existing policies. Over the last years, EU countries have implemented a number of measures to reduce methane emissions in the future, which are summarised in table A10.1:
Table A10.1: recent measures to reduce methane emissions in the EU
Sector Member States Technique applied
Agriculture Denmark Community-scale anaerobic digestion for manure applied to 3.2% of dairy cows, 1.6% of other cattle, and 32% of pigs
Coal mining Several Gas recovery with flaring applied to between 28% and 63% of countries emissions from mining
Gas distribution EU15 Replacement of 60% of grey cast iron networks and increased networks leakage control
Gas transmission Estonia, Reduced leakage at compressor stations, applied to 20%
pipelines Lithuania
Gas and oil EU15 Flaring of emissions from oil and gas production and processing
production and processing Energy Several Wood burning in domestic sector -replacement and change of
combustion countries boilers to more energy and emission efficient boilers
Transport Several Fuel efficiency improvements
countries
Municipal solid Several Treatment through large-scale composting, recycling, incineration, waste countries or landfill with gas recovery, complying with the Landfill Directive
Industrial EU28 Extended aerobic treatment of industrial wastewater from food-, wastewater paper-, and organic chemical manufacturing industries
Domestic EU28 Extended collection and treatment of domestic wastewater partly wastewater with gas recovery
294
Source: Lena Höglund-Isaksson, Wilfried Winiwarter and Pallav Purohit (2013) Non-CO 2 greenhouse gas emissions, mitigation potentials and costs in EU-28 from 2005 to 2050, Part I: GAINS model methodology, 30 September 2013, IIASA, Laxenburg.
These measures are projected to deliver a decline of more than 20% of CH 4 emissions by 2020 compared to 1990 and 24% in 2030 compared to 2005 in the baseline (reference projections including meeting renewable targets and the effort sharing decision).
Especially large reductions occur for waste treatment, where the progressing implementation of current EU legislation on solid waste disposal and waste water management, particularly in the new Member States, will lead to a sharp decline of CH 4 emissions in the coming years of more than 50% in 2030
The second largest contributions to emission reductions will come from energy i.e. improved gas distribution networks, for which losses will be cut by about 45% up to 2030 as well as the reduced use and production of coal and gas. In contrast, emissions from the agricultural sector are to decrease by some 2 % compared to 2005 (Table A10.2).
Table A10.2: Baseline emissions of CH4 by SNAP sector (kilotons)
2005 2025 2030
Power generation 246 149 136
Domestic sector 1185 659 556
Industrial combustion 123 81 69
Industrial processes 663 641 632
Fuel extraction 2043 1170 1033
Solvents 0 0 0
Road transport 129 15 12
Off-road transport 15 15 14
Waste treatment 6657 3759 3598
Agriculture 9447 9511 9453
Sum 20508 16001 15504
2. D IFFERENCES BETWEEN M EMBER S TATES
There are large differences in the evolution of methane emission between Member States. Many new Member States will reduce their CH 4 emissions by 30-47%, mainly as a result of the implementation of EU waste management regulations and the on-going upgrades of gas distribution networks. In contrast, emissions in most old Member States would decline less, as much of the waste management legislation has already been implemented in the past. Also, emissions from the agricultural sectors contribute a larger share to total emissions, and this sector is not expected to dramatically reduce its emissions in the future. For instance, only marginal changes are anticipated for, e.g, Belgium, Denmark and Ireland.
Table A10.3: Baseline emissions of CH4 by country (kilotons and change relative to 2005)
reference reference ref % of 2005 ref % of 2005 2005 2025 2030 2025 2030
AUS 290 232 236 20% 20%
295
BELG 336 295 292 12% 13%
BULG 370 205 198 45% 46%
CROA 146 126 125 14% 14%
CYPR 39 32 38 18% 3%
CZRE 495 366 363 26% 27%
DENM 268 247 249 8% 7%
ESTO 49 48 46 3% 7%
FINL 216 189 190 12% 12%
FRAN 2983 2453 2437 18% 18%
GERM 2647 1821 1722 31% 35%
GREE 483 333 316 31% 35%
HUNG 428 243 226 43% 47%
IREL 610 600 595 2% 2%
ITAL 1965 1432 1394 27% 29%
LATV 87 68 67 22% 23%
LITH 161 126 120 22% 25%
LUXE 22 17 17 20% 21%
MALT 10 8 7 26% 32%
NETH 827 612 595 26% 28%
POLA 1773 1617 1564 9% 12%
PORT 570 458 445 20% 22%
ROMA 1245 1033 1009 17% 19%
SKRE 215 149 147 31% 31%
SLOV 103 83 80 20% 23%
SPAI 1635 1395 1371 15% 16%
SWED 280 226 231 19% 18%
UNKI 2234 1587 1423 29% 36%
EU28 20508 16001 15504 22% 24%
Source: IIASA
3. F URTHER REDUCTION POTENTIAL BEYOND THE BASELINE
Table A10.4 reports methane emissions by Member State in 2005, projected emissions in
2025 and 2030, and further emission reduction potential at zero cost for 2025 and 2030.
Table A10.4: CH4 emission by Member State (kilotons and change relative to 2005) in the baseline and by taking further measures (at zero cost or all available)
at zero at zero ref % of ref % of reference reference costs costs 2005 2005 zerocost zerocost
2005 2025 2030 2025 2030 2025 2030 2025 2030 AUS 290 232 236 231 231 20% 20% 21% 20% BELG 336 295 292 250 249 12% 13% 25% 26% BULG 370 205 198 185 174 45% 46% 50% 53%
CROA 146 126 125 105 100 14% 14% 28% 31% CYPR 39 32 38 28 32 18% 3% 28% 18% CZRE 495 366 363 349 343 26% 27% 30% 31%
DENM 268 247 249 206 205 8% 7% 23% 24% ESTO 49 48 46 40 38 3% 7% 18% 23% FINL 216 189 190 184 184 12% 12% 15% 15% FRAN 2983 2453 2437 2254 2234 18% 18% 24% 25%
GERM 2647 1821 1722 1723 1610 31% 35% 35% 39% GREE 483 333 316 308 292 31% 35% 36% 40% HUNG 428 243 226 209 195 43% 47% 51% 55% IREL 610 600 595 565 566 2% 2% 7% 7%
296
ITAL 1965 1432 1394 1227 1173 27% 29% 38% 40% LATV 87 68 67 57 54 22% 23% 34% 37% LITH 161 126 120 103 94 22% 25% 36% 42% LUXE 22 17 17 16 16 20% 21% 25% 27%
MALT 10 8 7 8 7 26% 32% 26% 32% NETH 827 612 595 557 555 26% 28% 33% 33% POLA 1773 1617 1564 1260 1174 9% 12% 29% 34%
PORT 570 458 445 416 404 20% 22% 27% 29% ROMA 1245 1033 1009 940 918 17% 19% 25% 26% SKRE 215 149 147 137 127 31% 31% 36% 41% SLOV 103 83 80 77 74 20% 23% 25% 28%
SPAI 1635 1395 1371 1189 1078 15% 16% 27% 34% SWED 280 226 231 225 229 19% 18% 20% 18% UNKI 2234 1587 1423 1476 1315 29% 36% 34% 41%
EU28 20487 16001 15504 14324 13672 22% 24% 30% 33%
The baseline would cut methane emissions 221 in 2025 compared to 2005 and 24% in 2030. with a very broad variability for individual Member States, ranging from a 45% reduction in
Bulgaria to a 2% reduction in Ireland. These changes not only result from changes in livestock but also from changes in the energy pattern such as changes in the production of gas and oil. Beyond the baseline reduction, a further 8% reduction could be delivered at zero cost with measures that are either cost neutral or pay for themselves through energy recovery, bringing the 2025 emissions to 30% below the 2005 level, with reductions between 7% and
51% at Member State level. In 2030 emission reductions at EU level could be 33% compared to 2005 based on a conservative assumption of using only currently available technologies.
297 A NNEX 11 D ETAILED ANALYSIS OF SPECIFIC OBJECTIVES RELATED TO THE
NECD
This Annex refers to the impacts of the policy options directly related to possible changes to the NEC D other than the costs and benefits related to the impact reduction options which have been described in Chapter 6 of this impact assessment.
1. O BJECTIVES
Chapter 4 outlined objectives where specific action under the NECD is relevant:
• Facilitate action on residual local compliance problems;
• Promote enhanced policy co-ordination at Member State and regional/local level;
• Incorporate Gothenburg Protocol obligations into EU legislation and ratify the protocol;
• Proportionately tap the pollution reduction potential of contributing sectors;
• Address background pollution; and,
• Improve the information base for assessing policy implementation and effectiveness.
In addition, options for simplification and clarification are explored in the spirit of smarter regulation.
2. P OLICY OPTIONS
In order to address the specific objectives outlined above, the following thematic areas (TAs) and issues and options were identified:
TA1 – Establish and implement NEC D national programmes for improved air quality governance
Option 1: Maintain the existing requirements for programmes and simply update the dates for the new reduction commitments for 2020 and 2025/30.
Option 2: National programmes light – as for Option 1, but in addition requiring that coherence with other relevant plans and programmes be ensured, in particular the air quality plans required under the AAQD 2008/50/EC and climate and energy policy/programmes.
Option 3: Comprehensive coherent national air pollution control programmes – as for Option 2 but in addition requiring that benefits for air quality be maximised, that the programmes be developed and reported in a harmonised way,
298 that the effectiveness of programmes be reviewed regularly, and that corrective action be taken where needed to meet the commitment.
TA2 - Establish and report emission inventories and projections for relevant pollutants
Option 1: Strict minimum to monitor achievements of all proposed reduction commitments related to any (new) pollutant for which a reduction commitment would be established, emission inventories and projections would have to be established and reported.
Option 2: Coherence with the Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution (CLRTAP) requirements, including the establishment and reporting to the Commission and the EEA of all emission/projection data under the CLRTAP protocols and decisions of the CLRTAP Executive Body, and in accordance with the
EMEP reporting plan (except POPs which are covered by EU POPs regulation 30 ).
TA3 – Establish environment monitoring and indicators
Option 1: No change of legislation, i.e. no obligation to monitor air pollution effects.
Option 2: Ecosystem monitoring representative of sensitive ecosystem types in the respective Member State, coordinated with the effects oriented monitoring programmes of the LRTAP Convention.
Option 3: Targeted ecosystem monitoring, focusing on Natura 2000 31 protected
areas for which EU legislation requires Member States to maintain a good conservation status.
Option 4: Comprehensive monitoring of air pollution health and ecosystem effects. Effects on ecosystems would be monitored both for protected areas and other ecosystems, while air pollution health monitoring would be required through collection of national health statistics.
TA4 – Simplify and streamline reporting legislation
Option 1: No change of legislation
Option 2: "Easy" simplification and harmonisation, by streamlining with the
requirement under the PRTR Regulation 32 and the Monitoring Mechanism Regulation (MMR) 33 , as well as reporting under the IED.
Option 3: Comprehensive streamlining, including the establishment of a fully harmonised EU system for reporting of emissions of "classical" air pollutants and greenhouse gases.
30 EU POPs Regulation (EC) No 850/2004 i of the European Parliament and of the Council of 29 April
2004 on persistent organic pollutants and amending Directive 79/117/EEC i 31 92/43/EEC Habitats Directive
32 Regulation (EC) No 166/2006 i
33 Regulation (EU) of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 May 2013
on a mechanism for monitoring and reporting greenhouse gas emissions and for reporting other information at national and Union level relevant to climate change and repealing Decision No 280/2004/EC
299 TA5 – Establish EU action on short-lived climate pollutants (SLCP)
Option 1: No change of legislation
Option 2: Coherence with CLRTAP: focus on taking action from sources with significant emissions of black carbon when implementing the PM2.5 ceiling.
Option 3: Comprehensive SLCF policy action on black carbon, and tropospheric ozone.
3. I MPACT ANALYSIS
Methodology
The analysis follows the guidelines for impact assessments 34 . General considerations
on the likely environmental, social and economic impacts, in particular
administrative burden, are included. In addition the obstacles for compliance (in
implementing the obligation) and opportunities for better regulation, in particular
simplification have been analysed to the extent possible.
Environmental impacts In addition to implementing the cost-effective reduction commitments to achieve the objectives of the TSAP 2013 the options are qualitatively analysed with respect to
environmental performance 35 . Those are related to, inter alia:
• ensuring the availability of better quality and more complete data and information (data quality/completeness);
• enabling better compliance with domestic and international targets, commitments and requirements (compliance with domestic and/or international commitments);
• enabling future policy actions on air quality and short-lived climate pollutants (future policy development/implementation).
Compliance aspects and opportunities for better regulation A qualitative analysis is provided of the degree of difficulty Member States would
face in complying with a given option 36 . To the extent applicable the policy options are also qualitatively assessed for coherence with the better regulation objective 37 ,
which aims to simplify and streamline legislation.
Economic impacts Economic impacts of obligations for the MS, SMEs and industry are assessed only for measures that are additional to already existing EU legislation and international law. (Thus the economic impacts of obligations already existing under the CLRTAP
and its protocols, for instance, are not assessed.) 5
The administrative burden on Member States is quantified on the basis of the EU "Standard Cost Model" for those cases where the costs have been deemed to be significant. For most options it has not been possible to distinguish the costs for
34 http://ec.europa.eu/governance/impact/index_en.htm 35 Ratings: + or – is used to denote positive or negative impacts respectively, = signifies no impact, +/-
low impact, ++/--, medium (significant) impact.
36 Ratings in terms of likeliness: low (LL), medium (ML) and high (HL).
37 Ratings in the range from negative, no influence and positive (--, 0, ++).
300 implementing a substantive obligation such as installing and running new ecosystem monitoring stations from the costs of providing the resulting information to the Commission. In those instances the sum of the two is given and termed "administrative burden".
Social impacts
Most options assessed in this annex will have minor social impacts, if any, and so these are not specifically addressed. The main (positive) social impact of the options is better public information on air quality issues.
Impacts on employment, industry and SMEs
The impacts of the pollution reduction options on employment, industry and SMEs are given in Chapter 6 and Annex 9. There are only negligible additional impacts and (substantive and administrative) costs on those sectors as a result of the options analysed in this annex, since the information needs from the sectors (such as activity data and information related to abatement technologies) are already covered by EU legislation, in particular under the PRTR Regulation and the MMR.
Administrative burden calculation
The EU Standard Cost Model was used to assess the costs on public authorities in the Member States. The costs were estimated for the preferred option and when possible also for the other options covered in this annex. Both recurring (annual) and one-off (initial) costs were assessed.
The costing model was developed in two steps. In a first step 4 Member State experts were contacted providing their estimates on labour time necessary to implement the relevant options with identified significant administrative cost. This input was generalised into a costing model for the EU28. The details on the calculations of additional costs are given in the appendix to this annex.
4. S PECIFIC IMPACTS OF THE POLICY OPTIONS
TA1 - Establish and implement NEC D national programmes for air quality governance
The following impacts were assessed for each option:
Environmental impacts
The extent to which the option rectifies the current lack of coordination between different administrative levels in developing and implementing national programmes, improves identification of cost-effective measures at the national and local level, and so improves compliance prospects (or at least reduces total policy costs due to efficient combinations of measures).
Compliance and better regulation
The extent to which Member States would face an additional burden to transpose the legal requirement involved (for instance for Option 1, MS have already transposed the national programmes obligations and so compliance would not be an issue). Also, the extent to which better regulation opportunities are facilitated (in terms of
301
streamlining administration and better coordinating efforts to reach the air quality objectives).
Economic impacts
There are no direct costs for industry and SMESs. The costs are entirely administrative on the public administration and the Commission and EEA. The administrative burden effort required of the MS to implement the option in practice has been quantified for the options (see appendix).
Comparison of options
The table below summarises the performance of the options in relation to the impacts assessed. Overall, Option 3 fully resolves the problems identified in the expost evaluations of the NEC Directive and in this IA.
302
Summary for TA 1 – National programmes
TA1 – Environ Com Economic Better Admin burden National mental pliance impacts regulation programmes impacts Option 1 - = LL - - 0 Initial cost Only update € 4.8 million the dates Annual cost € 0.17 million Option 2 - = ML 0 ++ Initial cost National € 4.8 million programmes Annual cost light € 0.17 million Option 3 - ++ ML ++ ++ Initial cost Comprehens Lower € 5.2 million ive national cost than Annual cost programmes cost€ 0.18 million optimum technical measures
It should be noted that the current LIFE+ programme may contribute to covering the costs related to MSs needs to develop national assessment tools for air quality assessment and management as part of their programme development.
TA2 Establish and report emission inventories and projections for relevant pollutants
Option 1: Strict minimum to monitor achievements of all proposed reduction commitments for pollutants. That is, for any new pollutant for which a reduction commitment would be provided, emission inventories and projections would have to be established and reported.
Environmental impacts
This is a necessary minimum to document compliance with the related reduction objectives.
Compliance and better regulation
Member States have already transposed the legal requirement in order to fulfil their obligations under CLRTAP and so compliance should not be an issue. Opportunities for better regulation are likely to be negligible.
Economic impacts
None (already required under international obligations (CLRTAP)).
Administrative burden
No change of administrative burden has been identified for the MS. The Commission and the EEA may have slightly decreased administrative burden due to harmonised reporting of emissions and projections for these substances, which facilitates EU reporting to the CLRTAP.
303
In summary
Overall this option partly resolves the problems identified in the ex-post evaluations of the NEC Directive and in this IA.
Option 2: Coherence with CLRTAP requirements, including the establishment and reporting to the Commission and the EEA of all emission/projection data under the CLRTAP protocols and decisions of the CLRTAP Executive Body, and in accordance with the EMEP reporting plan (except POPs which are covered by EU POPs regulation).
Environmental impacts
The requirement of producing the emission inventories and projections defined in EMEP reporting plan are covered under the CLRTAP to which the MS are Parties. The environmental impacts of this option are nevertheless likely to be significant since it provides complete information to EU citizens on emissions and projections for all classical air pollutants, including short-lived climate pollutants.
Compliance and better regulation
Member States have already transposed the legal requirement in order to fulfil their obligations under CLRTAP and so compliance should not be an issue. Opportunities for better regulation are likely to be significant particularly in the long term through better EU internal coordination between the MS and EU institutions (Commission and EEA).
Economic impacts
None (already required under international obligations).
Administrative burden
No change of administrative burden has been identified for the MS. The Commission and the EEA will gain in effectiveness due to harmonised MS reporting of emissions and projections for air pollutants, which facilitates EU reporting to the CLRTAP.
In summary
Overall this option fully resolves the problems identified in this IA.
Summary for TA 2 – Emission inventories/projections
TA2 – Environment Compliance Economic Better Emission al Impacts impacts regulation inventories/ projections Option 1 Strict + LL 0 0 minimum
Option 2 ++ LL + 0 Coherence with CLRTAP
TA3 – Establish environment monitoring and indicators
304
Option 1: No change of legislation, i.e. no obligation to monitor air pollution effects.
Environmental impacts
The emission reduction commitments are designed to reduce environmental impacts, and without data on the state of the environment, ex post assessment of the real impacts of the policy will remain extremely difficult. This will also substantially hamper future policy development.
Compliance and better regulation
Not applicable for compliance. Many opportunities for better regulation may be lost due to poor coordination between MS undertaking voluntary activities under the CLRTAP.
Economic impacts
None.
Administrative burden
Not applicable.
In summary
Overall this option does not address the problems and objectives identified in this IA.
Option 2: Ecosystem monitoring in sensitive ecosystems coordinated with the effects-oriented programmes of the LRTAP Convention.
Environmental impacts
Impact monitoring in protected ecosystems will allow assessment of the effectiveness of air policy and create synergy with the objectives and programmes under the LRTAP Convention. The option will substantially increase the knowledge base approach of the that Convention and help future EU policy development addressing transboundary air pollution and ecosystem effects.
Compliance and better regulation
Compliance obstacles are likely to be low. Most Member States have partly or fully implemented such monitoring programmes as part of their commitment under the LRTAP Convention.
Economic impacts
The economic impacts are on the public administration and assessed as administrative burden.
Administrative burden
The administrative cost includes the complementary setting up and operation of the monitoring compared to already existing monitoring of ecosystems, and the provision of the required information to the Commission and other bodies. The total cost for the monitoring in ecosystems is small although significant and detailed in annex A.
305
Option 3: Targeted ecosystem monitoring, focusing on Natura 2000 38 protected
areas for which EU legislation requires Member States to maintain a good conservation status.
Environmental impacts
Impact monitoring in protected ecosystems will allow assessment of the effectiveness of air policy and of the progress towards the protection of Natura 2000 sites (including ex post evaluation of overall policy effectiveness). The latter will substantially help future policy development in both AQ and nature and habitats protection.
Compliance and better regulation
Compliance obstacles are likely to be low. Opportunities for better regulation occur for better coordination in MS when defining and implementing management plans for the Natura 2000 areas in areas where air pollution is significantly influencing ecosystems by acidification and eutrophication.
Economic impacts
The economic impacts are on the public administration and assessed as administrative burden.
Administrative burden
The administrative cost includes the setting up and operation of the monitoring (similar to a substantive cost) and the provision of the required information to the Commission and other bodies. The total cost for the monitoring in ecosystems is significant and detailed in annex A.
In summary
Overall this option provides the minimum respond to the problems and objectives pursued in this IA.
Option 4: Comprehensive monitoring of air pollution health and ecosystem effects. Effects on ecosystems would be monitored both for protected areas and other ecosystems, while air pollution health monitoring would be required through collection of national health statistics.
Environmental impacts
Full information would be made available on the effectiveness of air pollution policy in reducing ecosystem and health impacts, and on progress towards national and EU objectives. Future policy development/implementation would greatly improve and allow also ex-post evaluation of the air quality impacts on human health and the environment.
Compliance and better regulation
Compliance obstacles are likely to be high since the collection of health data is mainly national policy (subsidiarity) and related to health expenditures.
38 92/43/EEC Habitats Directive
306
Opportunities for better regulation may be large for MS when defining and implementing management plans for public health and the environment.
Economic impacts
The economic impacts are on the public administration and assessed as administrative burden.
Administrative burden
The administrative cost includes the setting up and operation a comprehensive health and environment monitoring is likely to be significantly higher than Option 2, particularly for public health monitoring. The total cost for the monitoring in ecosystems is significant and higher than the Option 2 and detailed in annex A.
In summary
Overall this option provides a comprehensive response to the problems and objectives pursued in in this IA. However, this option is likely to pose significant challenges to implement and with high costs.
Summary for TA 3 – Environment monitoring
TA3 – Environ Com Economic Better Admin burden environment mental pliance impacts regulation monitoring impacts
Option 1 - No - - n.a. 0 - - n.a. change
Option 2 – ++ LL (- ) + Initial cost € 1,5 Ecosystem million. Annual cost € monitoring 2.4 million coordinated with LRTAP Convention
Option 3 – ++ LL (- ) ++ Initial cost € 4.5 Targeted Natura million Annual cost € 2000 ecosystem 7.5 million monitoring
Option 4 - ++ HL (- -) ++ Initial cost € 4.5 Comprehensive million Annual cost € monitoring 7.5 million
Health monitoring excluded
TA4 – Simplify and streamline reporting legislation
Option 1: No change of legislation
In summary
No distinctive environmental, compliance, economic or administrative implications, but overall this option does not pursue the objective for better regulation.
307 Option 2: "Easy" simplification and harmonisation, by streamlining with the requirement under the PRTR and MMD, as well as reporting under the IED. Ensuring coherence in MSs reporting under different pieces of EU legislation.
Environmental impacts
Streamlining of reporting instruments has positive and significant environmental impacts particularly in providing internally coherent data for national authorities, EU citizens and the EU as a whole.
Future policy development/implementation would greatly improve and also allow effective ex-post evaluation of air related policy (classical air pollutants and greenhouse gases).
Compliance and better regulation
Compliance obstacles are likely to be low. Opportunities for better regulation occur related to better coordination in MS. However at the EU institution level (Commission and EEA) the opportunities for better regulation will be limited.
Economic impacts
No economic impacts have been identified.
Administrative burden
The administrative cost for the public administration is likely to be insignificant. The administrative cost for the EU institutions will remain at the same level as today.
In summary
Overall this option provides the minimum response to the problems and objectives pursued in this IA.
Option 3: Comprehensive streamlining, including the establishment of a fully harmonised EU system for reporting of emissions of "classical" air pollutants and greenhouse gases.
Environmental impacts
A full harmonisation of reporting at the level of MS and EU will have great positive environmental benefits for national health and environmental authorities, EU citizens and the EU as a whole.
Future policy development/implementation would greatly improve and also allow comprehensive ex-post evaluation of the air quality policy.
Compliance and better regulation
Compliance obstacles are likely to be medium since the full harmonisation will require significant effort in MS and in the EU. Opportunities for better regulation may be large for MS and the EU.
Economic impacts
No economic impacts have been identified.
Administrative burden
308
The administrative cost for the public administration is likely to be small in the long term but significant in its initial phase for some MS. The administrative cost for the EU institutions (like the EEA) may be reduced.
In summary
Overall this option provides a comprehensive response to the problems and objectives pursued in in this IA. However, this option is likely to pose some
challenges to implement at this stage due to costs and efforts required.
Summary for TA 4 – Simplify and streamline
TA4 – Simplify Environmental Compliance Economic Better and streamline Impacts impacts regulation reporting Option 1 No = 0 n.a. n.a. change
Option 2 "Easy" + LL 0 + streamlining
Option 3 ++ ML = ++ Comprehensive
TA5 – Establish EU action on short-lived climate pollutants (SLCPs)
Option 1: No change of legislation
Overall this option does not address the problems objectives identified in the IA, namely to advance policy on short lived climate forcers.
Option 2: Coherence with CLRTAP and specifically the 2012 amendment of the CLRTAP Gothenburg Protocol.
Environmental impacts
The environmental impacts are likely to be significant and positive since MS will also have to take appropriate measures to reduce black carbon emissions, being harmful for human health and climate in the short term.
Future policy development/implementation will gain significantly from increased experience in applying measures not covered by EU legislation so far.
Compliance and better regulation
Compliance obstacles are unlikely (requirement under international obligations). Opportunities for better regulation are likely to exist but small for MS and the EU.
Economic impacts
Economic impacts are likely to be small if any.
Administrative burden
The administrative cost exists but is small since increased monitoring of black carbon emissions will be required. A detailed assessment is given in annex A.
In summary
Overall this option offers opportunities for MS at low or no cost, largely maintaining the subsidiarity in the precise choice of measure.
309 Option 3: Comprehensive SLCF policy action on black carbon, and tropospheric ozone.
Environmental impacts
The environmental impacts are likely to be significant and positive since MS will also have to take appropriate measures to reduce black carbon and methane emissions (an ozone precursor), being harmful for human health and climate in the short term.
Future policy development/implementation will gain significantly from increased experience in applying measures not covered by EU legislation so far and will allow the EU to promote international action on short-lived climate forcers.
Compliance and better regulation
Compliance obstacles are likely to be moderate since comprehensive action will demand resources and efforts in MS and EU institutions. Opportunities for better regulation are likely to be significant but for MS and the EU in better coordination of policy on air pollution and climate change.
Economic impacts
Economic impacts are likely to be significant but small (and not assessed here).
Administrative burden
The administrative cost is small since increased monitoring of black carbon emissions will be required. A detailed assessment is given in annex A.
In summary
Overall this option offers opportunities for MS at low cost, largely maintaining the subsidiarity in the precise choice of measure.
Summary for TA 5 – Action on SLCF
TA5 – Environ Com Economic Better Admin EU action mental pliance impacts regulation burden on SLCF impacts Option 1 - = n.a. 0 0 n.a. No change Option 2 + LL 0 0 Initial – Action cost on black €0.20 carbon million Option 3 - ++ ML (not + Initial Compreh assessed) cost ensive €0.20 action million
5. O PTION COMPARISON
The comparison of options for each of the identified topic areas is based on qualitative criteria related to the effectiveness, the efficiency and coherence in achieving the specific objectives defined in section 4.3. The ratings applied are no effect (0), low (L), medium (M) and high (H).
310
Table on comparison of options
Effectiveness Efficiency Coherence TA1 – Option 1 L L 0
National Option 2 M M M programmes Option 3 H H M
TA2 –
Emission Option 1 L L L
inventories/
projections Option2 H M H
TA3 – Option 1 0 0 0 environment Option 2 M H M monitoring Option 3 M M H
Option 4 H M H TA4 – Option 1 0 0 0 Simplify and Option 2 M M M streamline Option 3 H M H
reporting TA5 – EU Option 1 0 0 0 action on Option 2 M M M SLCF Option 3 H M H
6. P REFERRED OPTION FOR REVISING THE NEC D
The preferred option combines the aspects of effectiveness, efficiency and coherence with those of issues on overall cost, compliance, subsidiarity and balance between costs and benefits.
Table on preferred options
Preferred option Estimated cost (administrative burden)
TA1 – National Option 3: Comprehensive Initial cost:€ 5.2 million programmes coherent national air Annual cost: € 0.18 pollution control programmes –requiring that benefits for air quality be maximised … TA2 – Emission Option 2: Coherence with Insignificant inventories/ projections CLRTAP requirements …
TA3 – environment Option 2: Ecosystem Initial cost: € 1.5 million monitoring monitoring coordinated Annual cost: € 2.4 million with LRTAP Convention TA4 – Simplify and Option 2: "Easy" Insignificant streamline reporting simplification and harmonisation, Ensuring coherence in MSs reporting TA5 – EU action on SLCF Option 2: Coherence with Initial cost: € 0.20 million CLRTAP and specifically the 2012 amendment of the CLRTAP Gothenburg Protocol.
311 7. M ONITORING AND EVALUATION
The preferred options relate to changes in MS obligations with regard to the establishment and reporting of
• national air pollution control programmes;
• coherent emission inventories and projection for air pollutants;
• and ecosystem effects monitoring in protected areas;
The Commission supported by the EEA, will continue to annually collate the received data and information. This information will be discussed with the MS to systematically review and improve the effectiveness of the policy.
In addition, the CLRTAP regularly undertakes in-depth reviews of emission inventories and projections provided by the EU and its MS on which the EU will build any further efforts of improvements of the relevant legislation and practices.
312
A PPENDIX 11.1 S TANDARD COST MODEL FOR ASSESSMENT OF ADMINISTRATIVE
BURDEN
The overall costs incurred on Member States public administrations, SMEs, industry and others related to the choices of options may be defined as substantive costs and administrative costs. The substantive costs for the options related to the choice of pollution reduction options are given in Chapter 6. This appendix summarises the additional costs for the options detailed in Appendix 11.2. Most of the options have no significant costs. Some of the analysed options are in reality a mix of substantive costs and administrative costs, such as the implementation of ecosystem monitoring.
No additional administrative burden has been identified for SMEs and industry. The entire additional cost for the preferred combined option will be on public administration.
The MS labour costs are based on 2010 statistics from EUROSTAT as the average
cost for the (ISCO) categories 2 and 3 39 .
Options related to national programmes – TA1
The estimated amount of administrative burden to prepare and implement national programmes varies between MSs depending on the MS size, the level of internal work of the administration as compared to outsourced work and the level of emission reductions aimed in the programmes. Based on interviews with experts from Member States (IE, BE, NL and DE) a simplified costing model was develop that sets the number of workdays to develop and adopt the national programme depending on country size (small MS below 10 million inhabitants, medium MS 10 to 30 million inhabitants, and large MS with more than 30 million inhabitants) as well as the national labour cost rates. The estimates for work days are upper estimates for MSs and may in several cases be significant below the tabled levels.
Table A11.1: Number of days for the preparation of initial national air pollution control programme
High degree MS size/ of No outsource outsourcing outsourcing
Small MS 1000 800
Medium MS 1200 1100
Large MS 1400 1300
Table A11.2: Number of days per year for the maintenance of national air pollution control programme
39 EUROSTAT.
313
High degree
MS of No size/outsource outsourcing outsourcing
Small MS 200 100
Medium MS 250 200
Large MS 300 250
To the extent known, the degree of outsourcing of work in the specific MS was accounted for- if not directly available such information (on high degree of outsourcing)
was taken from the IA for the Monitoring Mechanism Regulation 40 . The administrative
costs for complying with the requirement to consult with the public or neighbouring MSs were assessed to be insignificant in comparison to the efforts required to map measures and assess their effectiveness and costs. The preferred option for TA 1 Option 3 assumes a revision of the plans on average every 5 years. The estimated costs refer to the initial costs and average annual costs thereafter. Based in the interviews with MS the administrative costs for Option 1 and 2 were estimated to be only some 10 per cent less than for Option 3.
Options related to ecosystem monitoring - TA3
Member States cost for the monitoring of ecosystem effects are based on information from voluntary activities under the CLRTAP (see also consultant report "NEC CBA
Report 3" 41 ). As some of the monitoring under the CLRTAP (in particular dry deposition
of nitrogen to ecosystems) can be very costly this impact assessment focuses on a core set of parameters for assessing air pollution ecosystem damage. The preferred option is to focus on obtaining information of air pollution effects on sensitive ecosystems in the respective Member State coordinated with effects-oriented ecosystems monitoring under the LRTAP Convention. Forests, grasslands and fresh water ecosystems are vulnerable and sensitive to air pollution. The number of ecosystems types defined under the Natura 2000 framework (categories 3, 6 and 9) has been used as a proxy of the number representative ecosystems types by Member State.
Each Member State would have to complement current effects-based ecosystem monitoring compared to current programmes under the LRTAP Convention and maintain at least one site per defined habitat type in these categories (table A11.3). Again the national labour costs were used to assess the costs for setting up, maintaining, analysing samples and reporting data.
Table A11.3: Number of habitat categories defined by Member States in categories 3
"Fresh water habitats" 6. " Natural and semi natural grassland formations" and 9
"Forests" that serve as a proxy for sensitive ecosystems
No of habits No of habits
Member State in category 3, Member State in category Member State No of habits in 6 and 9 3, 6 and 9 category 3, 6 and 9
40 SEC (2011) 1407 final
41 AEA, 2008
314
Austria 44 Germany 42 Poland 39
Belgium 26 Greece 44 Portugal 42
Bulgaria 49 Hungary 30 Romania 51
Croatia 42 Ireland 18 Slovakia 42
Cyprus 19 Italy 65 Slovenia 32
Czech Republic 38 Latvia 26 Spain 53
Denmark 21 Lithuania 27 Sweden 39
Estonia 25 Luxembourg 19 U. K. 28
Finland 32 Malta 9
France 59 Netherlands 22
As all Member States are parties to the LRTAP Convention they also participate in the effects-oriented monitoring programmes. It is therefore assumed that half of the sensitive ecosystem types are covered by on-going activities and that only complementing the current network with new sites entails administrative costs. The required working days per new site were taken from NEC CBA Report 3 and defined for the setting up of the site, annual sampling and reporting. The costs for chemical and physical analysis of samples were taken from the same report and adjusted for by the national labour costs (using the U.K. estimates to normalise) as outlined above.
Table A11.4: Cost for individual samples for the assessment of ecosystem damage 42 as assessed for the U.K, see Appendix 11.3
Parameter Frequency per year Cost per sample/ parameter Average annual cost
ANC 1 360 360
BS 0,25 360 90
Al, Al(KCl) 0,25 300 75
NO3 leach 1 216 216
C/N 0,25 576 144
N/P, N/K 0,25 1200 300 Arginine in foliage 0,5 300 150
Growth 1 1200 1200
2535
Options related to action on short lived climate forcers –TA5
Member States comprehensively report emissions and projections under CLRTAP for all main classical air pollutants. The 2012 amendment to the Gothenburg Protocol includes an obligation to establish and report emissions and projections of black carbon but that amendment is not yet in force. EMEP is currently revising the
42 Taken from NEC CBA Report 3, (AEA, 2008)
315 guidelines and the guidebook for emission inventories and projections and planned to be part of CLRTAP reporting obligations from 2014 onwards. This impact assessment considers the obligation related to black carbon as additional. It should be noted that the substantive cost related to the TA5 Option 2 refers to give priority to emission reduction measures which also significantly reduce black carbon is covered in the achievement of the overall reduction objectives for PM2.5 and thus part of the cost estimates in section xx.
Other significant administrative costs for MSs' administrations related to TA5 Option 2 occur only the first year for the updating and validation of the national inventory/projection system. The following years the additional costs to maintain and report are insignificant. It is assumed that the update and validation the first year corresponds to 40 days of work.
316
A PPENDIX 11.2 A DMINISTRATIVE COSTS BY M EMBER S TATE OF PREFERRED
OPTIONS (€)
National program Ecosystem monitoring BC inventories
Member State initial cost, € annual cost, € initial cost, € annual cost, € initial cost, €
Austria 222085 5552 109932 166683 11104
Belgium 394518 16438 76931 116646 13151
Bulgaria 22320 558 12304 18656 1116
Croatia 55040 1376 26006 39432 2752
Cyprus 165799 4145 35439 53735 8290
Czech Republic 93942 3416 29208 44286 3416
Denmark 267896 6697 63290 95964 13395
Estonia 50927 1273 14323 21717 2546
Finland 204219 5105 73519 111472 10211
France 380044 16288 144145 218559 10858
Germany 379406 14593 110320 167271 11674
Greece 191100 6949 68796 104311 6949
Hungary 47155 1179 15915 24131 2358
Ireland 287148 11486 46518 70532 11486
Italy 338020 13001 152109 230633 10401
Latvia 35857 896 10488 15903 1793
Lithuania 35232 881 10702 16226 1762
Luxembourg 300853 7521 64307 97505 15043
Malta 92708 2318 9387 14232 4635
Netherlands 256846 10274 50856 77109 10274
Poland 112595 4331 30401 46095 3464
Portugal 163571 5948 56209 85226 5948
Romania 47873 1741 19976 30289 1741
Slovakia 57533 1438 27184 41218 2877
Slovenia 105522 2638 37988 57599 5276
Spain 273002 11700 93016 141034 7800
Sweden 276734 11069 97134 147278 11069
UK 362428 15533 65237 98915 10355
317 A PPENDIX 11.3 M ONITORING OF EFFECTS OF POLLUTANTS IN THE ENVIRONMENT
A. Geographical coverage of ecosystem monitoring sites
Member States should ensure that their network of monitoring sites covers at least a representative selection of all 'natural habitat types of Community interest' as listed under points
"3. Freshwater habitats", 6. ”Natural and semi-natural grassland formations” and "9. Forests"
of Annex I to Directive 92/43/EEC i.
B. Key indicators, monitoring requirements and methodologies to use at monitoring sites in freshwater ecosystems.
Mandatory Related effect Minimum Existing monitoring Indicators frequency networks
(unit)
acid neutralizing Biological damage, Sampling from ICP Waters, national capacity: including sensitive yearly (in networks, data provided for ANC receptors (micro- and autumn turnover) ICP Modelling and Mapping (µeq/L) macrophytes and to monthly to calculate critical loads. diatoms); loss of fish (streams), stock or invertebrates.
C. Key indicators, monitoring requirements and methodologies to use at monitoring sites in terrestrial ecosystems.
Mandatory Related effect Minimum Existing monitoring
indicators frequency networks
(unit)
soil base Loss of soil nutrients Every 4 years, ICP Forests, ICP saturation: (nutrient imbalances, Integrated Monitoring, BS growth reduction, national networks, data (per cent) susceptibility to other provided for ICP stress factors) Modelling and Mapping to calculate critical loads.
Soil acidity Soil CEC, soil acidity, Every 4 year ICP Integrated Exchangeable Al, nutrient availability Monitoring Al KCl (mg/g)
soil nitrate Nitrogen saturation, Every year ICP Forests, ICP leaching nutrient imbalances, Integrated Monitoring, NO 3,leach changes in vegetation national networks, data (µeq/L/year) structure, loss of provided for ICP biodiversity Modelling and Mapping
318
carbon-nitrogen Nitrogen saturation, Every 4 years to calculate critical ratio nutrient imbalances, loads. C/N (g/g) changes in vegetation structure, loss of biodiversity, links to climate change. Nutrient balance Nitrogen saturation, Every 4 years, ICP Forests, ICP in foliage: nutrient imbalances, Integrated Monitoring, (N/P, N/K, N/Mg) changes in vegetation national networks, data (g/g) structure, loss of provided for ICP biodiversity Modelling and Mapping to calculate critical loads. Arginin in foliage: Soil nitrogen status Every 2 years ICP Integrated (µmol/g) Monitoring Caused by ozone: Reduced biomass, Every year, ICP Vegetation, Growth/yield reduced yield quantity ICP Forests, reduction and and quality, reduced Hourly input national networks. leaf/foliar damage photosynthesis parameters during (per cent) capacity, links to growing season Exceedance of global change. (ozone flux-based critical concentration, levels climate, soil water) (mmol m -2 projected leaf area)
1 ICP manuals (except ICP Modelling and Mapping) provide information on site selection criteria, and additional indicators to make a proper assessment of ecosystem status
319
ANNEX 12 D ETAILED A NALYSIS FOR M EDIUM C OMBUSTION P LANTS (MCP)
1. R ATIONALE FOR ACTION
The policy options described in Chapter 6 of this Impact Assessment entail the adoption of pollution control measures at the level of each Member State selected on the basis of highest cost-effectiveness. The resulting combination of measures includes further emission controls in the MCP sector. Annex 8 provides details on the estimated emission reductions and associated emission control costs for the MCP sector under the central case policy option 6C* described in Chapter 6.6.2 of the Impact Assessment. These emission reductions are estimated at 79 kiloton sulphur dioxide (SO 2 ), 108 kiloton nitrogen oxides (NOx), and 13 kiloton PM2,5 (PM), for total additional emission control costs of 220 M€/year.
This Annex sets out the deeper impact analysis of options to deliver emission reductions from MCP through an EU-wide legislative instrument. Introductory sections below also provide more details on the characteristics of the sector, already existing measures at Member State and international level and the data sets used.
2. C HARACTERISTICS OF THE SECTOR
2.1. Definition of MCP for the purpose of this assessment
The combustion of fuels (gas, liquid, and solid fuels, including biomass) is one of the main sources of emissions of NOx and, in case of solid and liquid fuels, particulate matter PM and SO2. Combustion plants are operated with a wide range of capacities, depending on their application. The “large” combustion plants (i.e. those having a rated thermal input of 50 MW or more) are mainly used for electricity generation, district heating and industrial applications. These plants are covered by several pieces of EU environmental law and their pollutant emissions are controlled via permit conditions based on the application of BAT and cannot exceed the EU-wide limits set for dust, NOx and SO2 in the Industrial Emissions Directive 2010/75 i/EU (IED) and its predecessors, Directive 2008/1/EC i on Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control (IPPC) and Directive 2001/80/EC i on Large Combustion Plants (LCP).
At the other end of the capacity spectrum are the “small” combustion plants, with a capacity of less than 1 MW, which are predominantly used for domestic or residential heating. Some of these plants are covered by the Ecodesign Directive 2009/125/EC i. The implementing rules adopted in this context, while initially focusing primarly on energy efficiency, will also include product standards limiting emissions of air pollutants (NOx, PM, carbon monoxide (CO), etc depending on the type of plant and fuel used) in view of the outstanding air quality challenges described in Chapter 3 and Annex 4. This work is currently ongoing.
The combustion plants considered in this Annex (as in Chapter 7) are those falling between the two categories described above. These "medium" combustion plants with a rated thermal input between 1 and 50 MW are used for a wide variety of applications,
320 including electricity generation, domestic/residential heating and cooling, providing heat/steam for industrial processes, etc. Therefore, MCP should be considered not as a single sector but as a cross-sectoral activity relevant for the industrial, tertiary/commercial and residential/domestic sectors alike. Furthermore, a number of different technologies are concerned including boilers, heaters, engines and turbines. The focus of this assessment is on hot water and steam boilers, industrial process heaters, combined heat and power (CHP) plants, gas, dual fuel and diesel engines and gas turbines, in order to provide a basis for defining consistent regulatory approaches. However, it does not cover industrial dryers, process kilns and furnaces in which there is direct contact between the combustion waste gases and the materials processed or produced (such as cement clinker, lime, ceramics or asphalt kilns, wood dryers, glass furnaces, non-ferrous metals furnaces, coke ovens, etc.), chemical reactors, and waste incineration or co-incineration plants. That is because these relate to different technologies some of which are being considered for regulation separately (e.g. furnaces).
It is furthermore noted that emissions of air pollutants from MCP are not yet regulated at an EU level except where these plants are part of an installation covered by the IED either as a "directly associated activity" to an IED activity operated within the installation (e.g. combustion plants providing heat or steam to an industrial process listed in Annex I of IED) or where the plant is part of a wider combustion activity on site with a total rated thermal input of 50 MW or more (in line with the aggregation rule set out in the chapeau to Annex I of the IED).
2.2. Development of an EU-wide dataset
As part of recent studies, data on combustion plants smaller than 50 MW was gathered directly from the Member States. This included data on numbers, capacities, fuel consumption and emissions from the plants, as well as information on relevant national legislation (where applicable), combustion techniques used, abatement measures typically applied, and the degree to which the combustion plants may already be regulated under the IED.
From these Member State data and through extrapolation based on a number of assumptions, an EU wide dataset concerning MCP was developed with which possible control options were assessed. Based also on the above mentioned characteristics of the sector, the dataset was separated into three capacity classes of 1-5 MW, 5-20 MW and 20-50 MW rated thermal input, each covering a comparable share of the fuel used and emissions from the MCP segment. However, the number of plants within each of the three classes is very different (see Table A12.1). While there are more than 100,000 combustion plants between 1 and 5 MW, the group between 5 and 20 MW counts 23,000 plants, while there are only about 5,000 plants between 20 and 50 MW). Also, the combustion technologies, dominant fuel types and application of certain technical measures to abate emissions may differ between these categories. By considering the three classes separately, the impacts of the various options could be considered in more detail, in particular where they might depend on the number of plants affected or on the technical applicability of certain measures.
Data was also collected on the combustion technology used. However, very limited information could be found on this, and there was significant variation for the Member
321 States that have provided an indication of the split. Due to this limitation the technology types have been categorised into two groups: "boilers" and "turbines and engines". For Member States where no indication of the distribution between these two categories has been identified, the split has been assumed to be 80% boilers and 20% turbines and engines for each of the three size categories, which is based on the average of the available data.
2.3. Reference situation in 2010
The reference dataset mentioned above has been compiled from sources dating from
2008 to 2012, and has therefore been taken to offer a good basis for establishing a detailed reference case for 2010 to underpin the present assessment.
Table A12.1 provides an overview of the reference situation (2010) of MCP operated in
the EU-27 (number of plants, capacity, fuels used, emissions of SO2, NOx, and PM 43 ).
It shows that the dominant fuel used in MCP is natural gas with 67% of the total fuel use (64% for 1-5 MW, 73% for 5-20 MW and 60% for 20-50 MW). Solid (biomass, coal) and liquid fuels each have a share of about 12%. In some countries the main fuel used differs significantly from the overall EU average (AMEC 2013b). It also shows that, whilst the three capacity classes are comparable in terms of total rated thermal input (40% for plants 1-5 MW, 34% for plants 5-20 MW and 26% for plants 20-50 MW), the 1-5 MW group outnumbers the other ones in terms of plant numbers (80%).
Table A12.1: Medium size combustion plants in EU-27 – reference situation 2010
Total Rated thermal input: 1-5 MW 5-20 MW 20-50 MW 1-50 MW
Number of plants 113809 23868 5309 142986 Total rated thermal
input (GW) 274 232 177 683
Annual fuel consumption (PJ/year): 1971 2325 1410 5705
Biomass 163 160 182 505
Other solid fuel 49 46 74 169
Liquid fuel 213 290 206 709
Natural gas 1268 1704 844 3816
Other gaseous fuel 277 125 104 506
SO 2 emissions (kt/year) 103 130 68 301
NO x emissions (kt/year) 210 227 117 554
PM emissions (kt/year) 17 20 16 53
The three classes are also quite comparable in terms of emissions for the three pollutants considered. The 5-20 MW segment has the highest emissions (38-43% depending on the
43 Throughout this Annex, emission data concerning particulate matter is expressed as PM (particulate matter of any size). The relationship between PM and PM2.5 is complex and depends on the fuel used, the combustion technology and the abatement measures applied. For the existing stock of MCP a rough estimate is that the ratio between PM2.5 and PM is within the 30%-80% range. For the analysis presented in Chapter 7 of the Impact Assessment a factor of 50% is considered.
322
pollutant), closely followed by the 1-5 MW (32-38%) and the 20-50 MW (21-30%) segments. This reflects the fuel use split across capacity classes and the fact that the larger plants are more often and/or more strictly regulated at Member State level.
This is illustrated further in Figures A12.1 and A12.2.
Figure A12.1: Number of MCP and capacity (2010)
Figure A12.2 – Emissions (ktonnes/year) from MCP per capacity class for EU-27 (2010)
323 Table A12.2 provides a more detailed overview per Member State of the number of MCP and their total rated thermal input, split over the three size classes and Table A12.3 provides a similar overview of the 2010 emissions of SO 2 , NOx and PM.
324 Table A12.2: Number of plants and capacity per Member State (2010)
Number of plants Total capacity (MWth)
Size category 1-5 MW 5-20 MW 20-50 MW 1-5 MW 5-20 MW 20-50 MW
AT 2.516 441 110 5.979 5.193 3.471
BE 2.926 904 147 6.668 8.687 4.739
BG 1.670 434 73 3.968 4.136 2.305
CY 172 36 3 370 260 114
CZ 4.068 748 175 8.492 7.166 5.247
DE 35.500 3.480 767 84.354 33.170 26.227
DK 6.020 1.564 263 14.303 14.910 8.674
EE 537 174 29 1.203 1.794 1.025
EL 254 66 11 604 629 366
ES 5.811 1.510 254 13.807 14.392 8.373
FI 136 140 133 550 2.100 6.430
FR 13.399 2.951 1.600 31.839 28.124 52.744
HU 1.967 511 86 4.675 4.873 3.822
IE 1.397 363 61 3.319 3.460 2.013
IT 6.268 1.629 274 14.894 15.526 9.300
LT 889 231 39 2.112 2.202 1.281
LU 137 36 6 326 340 198
LV 641 144 28 1.926 1.898 1.157
MT 72 9 - 157 62 -
NL 6.995 2.250 110 21.000 23.000 3.700
PL 5.628 1.462 246 13.372 13.939 8.238
PT 778 202 34 1.848 1.927 1.176
RO 790 370 102 1.595 2.722 3.090
SE 916 784 198 2.749 9.405 6.913
SI 2.018 168 18 4.864 1.783 501
SK 1.986 581 91 4.223 5.114 2.695
UK 10.317 2.681 451 24.516 25.555 13.300
Total 113.809 23.868 5.309 273.714 232.367 177.099
325 Table A12.3: Emissions (ktonnes/year) per Member State (2010)
Emissions 2010 (kt/year)
1-5 MW 5-20 MW 20-50 MW TOTAL 1-50 MW
SO2 NOx PM SO2 NOx PM SO2 NOx PM SO2 NOx PM
AT 2.1 1.8 0.1 0.1 1.5 0.0 0.1 2.5 0.1 2.3 5.9 0.2
BE 5.1 15.3 1.4 6.6 19.9 1.9 3.6 10.9 1.0 15.4 46.1 4.3
BG 3.3 4.1 0.5 5.4 6.7 0.7 1.6 2.4 0.3 10.3 13.2 1.6
CY 0.6 0.1 0.6 0.4 0.1 0.3 0.5 2.0 0.0 1.5 2.2 0.9
CZ 1.8 1.9 0.3 1.2 2.0 0.3 4.1 2.2 0.2 7.1 6.1 0.9
DE 26.0 76.0 2.5 10.2 29.9 1.0 8.1 23.6 0.8 44.3 129.5 4.3
DK 11.5 8.5 1.5 19.1 11.3 2.0 4.5 8.8 1.2 35.1 28.6 4.6
EE 4.4 0.6 1.1 0.6 0.8 1.0 4.0 0.5 1.4 9.1 1.8 3.5
EL 0.5 0.6 0.1 0.8 1.0 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.1 1.5 2.0 0.2
ES 7.5 12.1 1.0 12.5 20.1 1.3 1.5 4.1 0.4 21.5 36.3 2.6
FI 0.6 1.7 0.2 1.8 1.9 0.3 3.7 4.4 0.3 6.0 8.0 0.9
FR 9.8 19.2 2.0 8.7 17.0 1.8 8.0 10.3 2.5 26.5 46.5 6.2 HU 1.6 2.9 0.1 2.6 4.7 0.1 2.1 2.7 0.3 6.4 10.3 0.5 IE 5.3 4.3 0.7 8.8 7.1 0.9 2.1 2.2 0.6 16.2 13.7 2.2
IT 9.4 12.9 0.8 15.6 21.5 0.9 3.7 9.1 0.7 28.7 43.6 2.5
LT 2.2 2.2 0.3 3.7 3.7 0.3 0.9 1.3 0.2 6.8 7.3 0.8
LU 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.8 0.0
LV 0.9 1.7 1.5 1.3 2.6 1.8 0.5 1.5 0.5 2.7 5.8 3.7
MT 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0
NL 0.0 8.6 0.0 0.0 11.7 0.0 0.0 1.6 0.0 0.0 21.9 0.0
PL 0.8 9.4 0.3 13.0 18.7 2.0 11.0 5.4 4.0 24.8 33.4 6.2
PT 1.7 2.4 0.5 2.9 3.9 0.8 1.0 2.6 0.4 5.5 8.9 1.7
RO 0.7 1.4 0.1 2.0 3.8 0.3 1.5 3.7 0.3 4.2 8.8 0.7
SE 0.2 1.8 0.3 2.2 5.6 0.5 0.7 3.5 0.2 3.1 10.9 1.1
SI 0.1 1.4 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.0 0.4 2.1 0.3
SK 0.1 0.7 0.2 0.2 1.1 0.1 0.2 1.2 0.1 0.6 3.0 0.4
UK 7.0 18.7 1.0 9.4 30.1 1.6 4.0 9.0 0.6 20.4 57.8 3.1
EU-27 103.3 210.5 17.2 129.6 227.3 20.0 67.6 116.7 16.2 300.5 554.5 53.4
Table A12.4 provides an overview of EU-27 emissions in 2010 split per fuel type. For this assessment, five different fuel types have been assumed (the same ones that have to be reported on by Member States under the LCP Directive 2001/80/EC i and the IED). The category “other solid fuel” covers coal and lignite, while “gaseous fuel other than natural gas” mainly concerns biogas, which is predominantly used in Germany. It shows that different fuel groups are associated with the largest share of emissions of the three pollutants concerned: SO 2 emissions are mainly related to the use of liquid fuels (some 62%), NOx emissions are strongly associated with natural gas firing and PM emissions are highest from biomass firing, in particular for the smaller combustion plants (up to 20 MW).
326 Table A12.4: Emissions per fuel type for EU-27 (2010) (ktonnes per year)
Emissions 2010 (kt/year) per fuel type
BIOMASS OTHER LIQUID NATURAL GASEOUS TOTAL
SOLID FUEL GAS FUEL
EU-27 FUEL OTHER THAN
NATURAL
GAS
Capacity class SO2
1-5 MW 13.8 16.8 64.5 - 8.1 103.3
5-20 MW 8.7 26.1 91.2 - 3.5 129.6
20-50 MW 10.4 21.7 30.4 - 5.1 67.6
TOTAL 1-50 MW 33.0 64.7 186.1 - 16.7 300.5
NOx
1-5 MW 22.6 11.7 21.5 134.4 20.1 210.5
5-20 MW 17.4 7.5 30.1 163.7 8.7 227.3
20-50 MW 14.7 9.1 13.6 72.8 6.6 116.7
TOTAL 1-50 MW 54.7 28.3 65.2 370.9 35.4 554.5
PM
1-5 MW 7.7 2.3 7.2 - - 17.2
5-20 MW 8.3 4.0 7.8 - - 20.0
20-50 MW 4.4 5.5 6.2 - - 16.2
TOTAL 1-50 MW 20.4 11.8 21.2 - - 53.4
2.4. Overview of current regulation
2.4.1. EU legislation
Currently, there is no EU legislation specifically addressing air emissions of polluting substances from combustion plants between 1 and 50 MW except for the cases set out below.
As mentioned, combustion units with a rated thermal input less than 50 MW may already be regulated under Directive 2010/75 i/EU on industrial emissions (IED) as part of installations where the combustion is a directly associated activity with a technical connection to the IED activity as well as where the total on-site combustion capacity is exceeding 50 MW. In those cases, the installation has to be operated in accordance with a permit issued by the competent authorities in the Member States, which contains conditions including emission limit values or equivalent provisions for the key polluting substances that are emitted, as well as monitoring requirements. These conditions have to be based on the application of the best available techniques (BAT).
327 Data was collected from Member States to identify the share of MCP that are part of IED installations. Although it is apparent that this may be the case for a greater proportion of 20-50 MW combustion plants compared to plants below 20 MW, the available information was not sufficiently robust to allow a quantitative estimate of the proportions per Member State.
A rough estimate is that 5% of plants in the 1-5 MW class, 10% of plants in the 5-20 MW class and 40% of plants in the 20-50 MW class are part of IED installations and, therefore, subject to the obligation to be covered by a BAT-based permit.
Council Directive 1999/32/EC i of 26 April 1999 relating to a reduction in the sulphur
content of certain liquid fuels 44 requires Member States to ensure that heavy fuel oils
are not used within their territory if their sulphur content exceeds 1% by mass. Until 31 December 2015, heavy fuel oils having a higher sulphur content may be used under certain conditions in combustion plants which do not fall under Directive 2001/80/EC i (Large Combustion Plant Directive) when their monthly average SO 2 emissions do not exceed 1 700 mg/Nm³ (3% reference oxygen content) 45 . As from 1 January 2016, the
same exemption applies under the abovementioned conditions for heavy fuel oils burned in combustion plants which do not fall within the scope of Chapter III of IED. In practice this means that SO 2 emissions from liquid fuel fired medium size combustion plants shall not be higher than 1 700 mg/Nm³. This Directive also sets a limit of 0,1% by mass for the sulphur content of gas oil.
2.4.2. Gothenburg Protocol
The Protocol to abate acidification, eutrophication and ground-level ozone (Gothenburg Protocol) was adopted in 1999 by the Parties to the Convention on Long-Range
Transboundary Air Pollution (CLRTAP). 46 It entered into force in 2005 and sets
emission ceilings for 2010 for four air pollutants: sulphur, nitrogen oxides, volatile organic compounds and ammonia. It also sets emission limit values for the key source categories (stationary, mobile and products). The Gothenburg Protocol was amended in 2012 to include national emission reduction commitments to be achieved in 2020 and beyond (See also Chapter 3 and Annex 4). Several of the annexes containing emission limit values to be adhered to by Parties were revised with updated sets of emission limit values and emission ceilings for fine particulate matter were added. The source-related annexes mostly cover combustion plants over 50 MW, but for some categories the threshold is lower than 50 MW. Annexes which are relevant to MCP can be summarised as follows:
• Annex IV: limit for sulphur content of gas oil: <0.1% by January 2008 (transposed in EU legislation via Directive 1999/32/EC i, see above);
• Annex V (NOx): limit values for new stationary engines (gas engines and dual fuel engines greater than 1MW and diesel engines greater than 5MW) : limits vary between 95 and 225 mg/Nm³ (15% O 2 ) depending on the engine type and fuel
44 OJ L 121, 11.5.1999, p. 13, as last amended by Directive 2012/33 i/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 November 2012 (OJ L 327, 27.11.2012, p.1)
45 1700 mg/Nm³ represents the maximum emission level that would result from firing heavy fuel oil containing 1% sulphur (unabated emissions).
46 http://www.unece.org/env/lrtap/multi_h1.html
328 used; exemptions may be granted for plants running less than 500 hours per year or plants used in particular local conditions;
• Annex X (dust 47 ): non-binding emission levels for solid and liquid fuel fired
boilers and process heaters between 1 and 50 MW: these levels vary between 20 and 50 mg/Nm³ depending on the size and plant age (at various reference oxygen contents, depending on the fuel type).
Compliance with the emission limit values is not the only compliance option for Parties. Alternatively ‘different emission reduction strategies that achieve equivalent overall emission levels for all source categories together’ may be applied. The Protocol nevertheless requires that, ‘Each Party should apply best available techniques (…) to each stationary source covered by [the] annexes[…] , and, as it considers appropriate, measures to control black carbon as a component of particulate matter[…]. .
2.4.3. Member States’ national legislation
Several Member States have already taken action to reduce air pollution from MCPs in view of meeting present air quality standards and emission ceilings. From earlier information gathering it was clear that the emission limits applied nationally (or regionally) differed significantly across Member States. Some Member States have recently revised their legislation thereby establishing more stringent limit values for MCP.
Table A12.5 summarises the most recently information gathered on Member States’ national legislation regulating combustion plants below 50 MW. It shows that at least 15 Member States are regulating all or part of the MCP, through a permit, emission limit values and/or monitoring requirements. In addition, some Member States set permit
conditions for these plants on a case-by-case basis. 48
47 “dust” is a term used in Annex X, Part A of the Gothenburg Protocol (as amended in 2012) in the context of particular matter emissions, with the following explanation given: "In this section only, “dust” (…) means the mass of particles, of any shape, structure or density, dispersed in the gas phase at the sampling point conditions which may be collected by filtration under specified conditions after representative sampling of the gas to be analysed, and which remain upstream of the filter and on the filter after drying under specified conditions." Hence, the term is equivalent with the term “PM” used elsewhere in this Annex.
48 No information was obtained for Bulgaria, Croatia, Denmark, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania,
Luxembourg and Malta.
329 Table A12.5: Overview of national legislation regulating combustion plants below 50 MW
MS Legislation Permitting Emission Monito limits ring obligat ions
AT BGBI.II Nr. 312/2011 concerning furnaces which are not No steam boilers
BGBI Nr.19/1989 idf. BGBL. II Nr. 153/2011 concerning steam boilers and gas turbines <50 MW.
BE/ FL VLAREM II (Order of the Flemish Government of 1 June 1995 concerning General and Sectoral provisions relating
to Environmental Safety). BE / WA Unknown reference Unknown
CY The Control of Atmospheric Pollution (Non Licensable No Installations) Regulation of 2004 (P.I. 170/2004)» as
amended in 2008 by Regulations of 2008 (P.I. 198/2008) CZ Government Ordinance No. 146/2007 Coll. In wording No
No. 476/2009 Coll. (ELVs) Decree No. 205/2009 Coll. In wording No. 17/2010 Coll. (Monitoring)
EE Välisõhu kaitse seadus, Vastu võetud 05.05.2004 (permit RT I 2004, 43, 298 (ambient air protection act) specific) (permit specific )
FI Environmental Protection Act Unkno Government Decree on environmental protection wn requirements for energy production installations with a
total fuel capacity < 50 MW FR Inspection des Installations Classées
(Permitting – separate regimes for 2-20MW and 20- 50MW) NOR: ATEP9760321A Version consolidée du 15/12/2008 (ELVs 2-20MW) ELVs for >20MW (various regulations, depending on age of plant)
DE (Verordnung über kleine und mittlere Feuerungsanlagen - 1. BImSchV (ELVs)
Technical Instructions on Air Quality Control – TA Luft (24 July 2002) (Monitoring)
IE Air Pollution Act 1987 (IPPC related activities) Only for IPPC related activities NL BEES-B (Existing installations <50MW th ) (general BEMS (New installations and existing installations from binding 2017 on) rules) PL Environmental Protection Law (Permits) Not required Emission standards regulation (ELVs for 1-50MW th ) Rozporzñdzenie Ministra Ârodowiska (Monitoring) PT Decree-Law 78/2004 49 Ordinance 675/2009 50
RO Ministerial Order no 1798/2007 for the approval of the procedure of issuing the environmental permit
ELVs in accordance with Ministerial Order no. 462/1993 – Technical conditions regarding air protection, Annex 2
SK References unknown
49 http://dre.pt/pdf1s/2004/04/080A00/21362149.pdf
50 http://dre.pt/pdf1sdip/2009/06/11900/0410804111.pdf
330
MS Legislation Permitting Emission Monito limits ring obligat ions
SI UREDBO o emisiji snovi v zrak iz malih in srednjih kurilnih naprav
SE Permit conditions for plants are set on a case-by-case Unknown Case-by? basis. case basis
ES ELVs are set by Autonomous Communities. X X X General binding rules do not exist.
UK Environmental Permitting, England and Wales (2010) – (>20MW) Part B Regulations apply to boilers 20-50MW th (>20MW) (>20M W)
3. P OLICY OPTIONS
Based on the needs defined as part of the central impact and emission reduction case in chapter 6 and the developed insights of the MCP sector as well as stakeholder inputs (also reported in in the main impact assessment), a set of policy options have been identified. These have been defined in terms of the emission levels hat would be set and the regulatory procedures that would be followed.
3.1. Options determining the emission levels
Five policy options have been considered that differ in environmental emission level for reducing the emissions of SO 2 , NOx and PM from MCPs:
• Emission level option 1: no EU action
This default option assumes continuation of current policy measures at Member State level and no further measures for controlling emissions of SO 2 , NOx or PM from MCP in the EU. It serves as a reference to calculate the impacts of the other policy options.
• Emission level option 7A: “most stringent MS”
Under option 7A, EU wide emission limit values for SO 2 , NOx and PM are set for all MCP (both new and existing) at the level of the most stringent legislation which is currently applicable in Member States for existing plants (for each of the fuel types and size classes considered).
• Emission level option 7B: “LCP”
Option 7B is the application of the EU wide ELVs for all MCP (both new and existing) which are set out in the IED for existing combustion plants with a rated thermal input between 50 and 100 MW (Part 1 of Annex V of the IED).
• Emission level option 7C: “primary NOx”
A variation of the option 7B, affecting only NOx, such that the only abatement measures required to be taken up for NOx would be combustion modifications (primary measures) and no secondary (end-of-pipe) measures. For SO 2 and PM the emission levels under this option are the same as for option B.
• Emission level option 7D: “Gothenburg”
Option 7D is a variant of option 7C, whereby EU wide ELVs for NOx, SO2 and PM
are differentiated for new and existing plants. It has been designed following
331 analysis of previous options and to consider possible additional lower cost options (see section 3.3.5 on mitigation measures). It takes into account (i) that a longer application deadline could be set for existing plants than new plants (e.g. ELVs enter into force in 2022 for existing plants instead of 2018 when it would apply for new plants); (ii) that MCPs operating a limited amount of hours (less than 300 hours/year) are exempted from complying with the ELVs for all the pollutants to avoid excessive costs for minimal benefit, (iii) that secondary abatement measures for NOx will be cheaper to implement in new built plants as compared to retrofitting existing stock (see section 3.1.2); (iv) the need to align ELVs with those set out in the amended Gothenburg Protocol.
• Emission level option 7E: “SULES”
Option 7E is a variation of option 7D, where the ELVs for new plants have been set according to the existing or future applicable ELVs for most stringent Member States.
A summary of the emission values corresponding to the above described assumptions and used for assessing the impacts of the different options is given in Appendix 12.1.
3.2. Regulatory options
Apart from the emission level options set out in section 2.1, which determine the environmental outcome, four different regulatory options have been considered and assessed. They vary mainly in terms of the administrative approach (and cost) through which MCP would be regulated, in particular whether or not a permit would be required.
• Regulatory option R1: "integrated permit"
Under this option derived from the IPPC permitting regime, the operators of the combustion plants would be required to obtain an integrated permit issued by competent authorities in the Member States for operating the plant. This permit would cover all relevant environmental impacts of the plant’s operation. In addition to the EU-wide emission limit values for emissions of SO2, NOx and PM to air the permit may also, where relevant, set conditions concerning emissions to water and soil, as well as for energy use and waste generation. The public would have a right to participate in the decision-making process and this is also taken into account for the assessment.
• Regulatory option R2: "air emissions permit"
Under this option, the operators of the combustion plants would be required to obtain a permit issued by competent authorities in the Member States, which would cover only emissions to air coming from the plant’s operation. In addition to the EU- wide emission limit values for SO2, NOx and PM, the permit would also set the associated requirements for monitoring and reporting.
• Regulatory option R3: "registration"
Under this option, combustion plant operators would have to notify operation of the MCP (and the key administrative and technical information) for registration by the competent authorities in the Member States. The authorities would keep a register of the notified plants. The plants would be subject to the EU-wide emission limit values and monitoring requirements for SO2, NOx and PM.
332 • Regulatory option R4: "general binding rules"
Under this option, MCP operators would not be obliged to obtain a permit, nor to notify competent authorities. Plants would be subject to the EU-wide emission limit values for SO2, NOx and PM to air and associated monitoring requirements.
The requirement under options R1 and R2 for each plant to have a permit would allow the consideration of the need for stricter conditions in order to ensure compliance with local air quality standards. In contrast with option R4 option R3 would allow mapping emissions of medium size plant and therefore improve knowledge and emission inventories, which would not be possible with option R4.
4. I MPACT A NALYSIS
4.1. Methodology, assumptions and uncertainties
4.1.1. Main methodology
The environmental, economic and social impacts of the options described in the previous section have been assessed on the basis of both quantitative and qualitative analysis. Impacts under emission level options 7A-7E were compared to those under option 1 (no EU action). For the administrative costs, the impacts of the regulatory approaches R1 to R4 were considered.
Emission reductions (reflecting environmental benefits), compliance costs (implementation of emission abatement measures), emission monitoring costs and administrative costs were calculated through a bottom-up modelling, using the database referred to in section 1.2 and described in more detail in the following sections.
The assessment of the abatement measures uptake, annualised compliance costs and emission reductions has been performed separately for the three capacity classes (1-5, 5- 20 and 20-50 MW) to reflect differences in emission levels and abatement measures applied. The emissions and costs have been estimated on the basis of the information gathered for the reference year 2010, projecting forward to 2025 and 2030. These 2025 and 2030 forecasts have been estimated by scaling the 2010 results by Member State, using fuel type specific growth factors, which were developed using PRIMES 2012 data on fuel consumption. The total fuel consumed across all of the sectors of interest for MCP has been calculated for each Member State by fuel type. The growth factor is calculated as the difference between the fuel consumption in the projection year (2025 or 2030) and the reference year (2010). The factor can be negative as the fuel consumption projections incorporate projected improvements in efficiency and turn-over of plants. Fuel consumption by MCP has been assumed to change in direct proportion to changes in fuel consumption for the relevant sectors as a whole within the Member State.
Impacts for options 7A, 7B and 7C were calculated for both the years 2025 and 2030 51 . It
is however generally noted that the trends for both years are very similar, with emissions and costs either the same or just a few per cent lower in 2030 as compared to 2025.
51 The analysis had been conducted under the assumption that all plants operated will comply with the EU wide ELVs set
under the options at the time of the projection year (either 2025 or 2030)
333
These differences are primarily related to changes in activity 52 as the ELVs are not
differentiated for new and existing plants, For options 7D and 7E impacts have been calculated for 2025 only but some differences are expected for 2030 as some of the ELVs for new plants are tighter than those for existing plants (and there will be a greater proportion of new plants in 2030 compared to 2025). Differences between 2025 and 2030 for option 7D are expected to be relatively minor as differences in costs will be mostly due to new engines and turbines - in 2030 they would represent about 3.4% of the total plants. The difference is expected to be much more pronounced for option 7E where variations between the ELVs applied for new and existing plants are large.
To avoid over complexity and to ease the comparison of options, only the results for
2025 will be presented and discussed, the full set of results obtained (for both the years
2025 and 2030) are reported in Appendices 12.2 and 12.3.
The bottom-up approach used for calculating the potential emission reductions and associated costs for MCP relies on an installation dataset (number of plants, fuels used, emissions, legislation in place) built up from Member State data and subsequently gapfilled, on literature data and expert judgement for applicable control measures and associated compliance costs. Inevitably, this involves a number of uncertainties and limitations, in particular concerning the input data and the modelling applied.
4.1.2. Uncertainties with respect to input data
The principal points to note concerning the installation dataset are the following:
• Greater uncertainty is associated with the data for smaller capacity classes due to their reliance on a greater proportion of extrapolation;
• Estimates for some of the larger Member States could have a disproportionate effect on the overall EU figures;
• Very limited information has been provided on sectoral breakdown and technology split and so for many Member States an average split had to be applied;
• Certain similar abatement techniques were combined into one group (e.g. different types of combustion modification).
4.1.3. Modelling assumptions
The approach for projecting emission reductions and costs was based on the current estimated plant stock (numbers, capacity, emissions etc.) dataset and then projected forward to 2025/2030 using PRIMES 2012 fuel consumption and activity data. The modelling further included the following assumptions:
Option 1 takes into account current legislation in each Member States. This option has been refined in the course of the assessment when modelling options 7D and 7E for 2025, to better take into account future emission limit values that have already been adopted by certain Member States. As a result, the compliance costs for options 7A, 7B and 7C may be slightly overstated for some Member States.
52 Annex 5 of the Impact Assessment 'Detail description of Future air quality projections Assuming No Change in
Current Policies'.
334
Control measures already implemented by Member States under their current legislation have been included under option 1. It is not necessarily the case that all of the combustion plants which are part of IED installations and hence should be covered by an integrated permit are already subject to such legislation. Although it may be expected that emission limits will already have been set in the permits for those plants, it could not be generally assessed at what level those limits would be set, except where national law is prescribing the limits (see section 1.4). Hence, only where such a limit was explicitly prescribed, MCP which are part of IED installations are assumed to be covered by it already. As a result, the overall costs and benefits associated with the policy options may be overstated for some Member States.
The administrative cost assessment assumes a static number of plants from 2010 until 2030 in the absence of any data on how this may change (total fuel consumption decreases by 13% over this period using the PRIMES 2012 data for combustion overall but this has been assumed to be related to energy efficiency improvements rather than a decline in plant numbers). Some Member States have reported that they expect the number of smaller plants to increase as there is a push for more decentralised heat and power supply. This could lead to an underestimation of the potential administrative costs.
In emission level options 7D and 7E new and existing plants have been modelled separately taking into account the ELVs that apply for each in the Member States in relation to national law (where available). In the calculations an average plant lifetime of 30 years has been assumed, corresponding to annual replacement rate (plant turnover) of 3.3%. The analysis assumes that the ELVs would apply to new plants from 2018 and to existing plants from 2022; the longer lead time for existing plant would allow planning any necessary upgrades within the normal investment cycle. In 2025 it is assumed that approximately 27% of plants in the EU would be new and have to meet the ELVs specified for new plants. The model considers that measures on new plants are 40% cheaper than measures on existing plants (retrofitting) for secondary (end-of-pipe) measures, and 60% for primary measures.
Options 7D and 7E take into account exemptions for plants operating less than 300 hours/year. This results in a reduction in costs in equal proportion (17,5%), while emissions are estimated to increase by only 1% due to the low number of operating hours (see details in section 3.3.6 on mitigation measures).
4.2. Environmental impacts
For each of the options 7A-7E, the emission reductions for SO 2 , NO x and PM in 2025 were assessed compared to "no EU action".
4.2.1. SO2 emissions
Table A12.6 presents the SO 2 emission forecasts for 2025. Without further EU action, SO 2 emissions of MCP are projected to decrease by 127 ktonnes (42%) due to changes in fuel mix (shift from coal to biomass) and activity. Under all the options 7A-7E total additional SO 2 emission reductions in 2025 (in comparison with option 1) are all very similar, ranging from 127 to 139 ktonnes.
Table A12.6: SO2 emissions (kt/year)
335
7B: LCP
Emission level 1: 7A: most 7E:
option: 2010 no EU stringent
and 7C: 7D:
action MS Primary Gothenburg SULES NOx
1-5 MW 103 58 9 13 13 11 5-20 MW 130 67 12 17 13 12 20-50 MW 68 49 14 17 14 13 TOTAL 1-50 MW 301 174 35 47 39 37
Total emission reduction
compared to "no EU action" 139 127 135 137
4.2.2. NOX emissions
Table A12.7 presents the NO X emission forecasts for 2025. Without further EU action,
NO X emissions of MCP are projected to decrease by 99 ktonnes (18%) due to changes in fuel mix and activity. In comparison with option 1, option 7B would further reduce emission by 303 ktonnes and under option 7A, the additional reduction would even be
338 ktonnes (i.e. 74% of 2025 emissions without EU action). When only primary NOx measures would be required (option 7C), the emission reduction compared to option 1 would be limited to 76 ktonnes (i.e. 17% of 2025 emissions without EU action).
Differentiating measures between new and existing plants as under option 7D would reduce emissions by 107 ktonnes compared to a 'no EU action' scenario, while with option 7E reductions of 159 ktonnes are achieved.
336
Table A12.7: NOx emissions (kt/year)
7A:
Emission 1: most 7B: 7C: 7D: 7E:
level option: 2010 no EU action stringent LCP primary Gothenburg SULES
MS NOx
1-5 MW 210 170 46 63 140 131 112 5-20 MW 227 188 47 62 149 140 119 20-50 MW 117 98 24 42 90 78 66 TOTAL
1-50 MW 554 455 117 167 379 348 297
Total emission reduction compared to 338 288 76 107 159
"no EU action"
4.2.3. PM emissions
Table A12.8 presents the PM emission forecasts for 2025. Without further EU action, PM emissions are projected to decrease by a mere 5 ktonnes by 2025, due to changes in fuel mix (reduction in coal use is neutralised by increase in biomass use) and activity. As for SO 2 , total additional PM emission reductions achieved by all options 7A-7E in comparison with option 1 are all very similar, ranging from 42 to 45 ktonnes.
Table A12.8: PM emissions (kt/year)
Emission level 1: 7A: most
7B: LCP 7E:
option: 2010 no EU stringent
and 7C: 7D:
action MS Primary Gothenburg SULES NOx
1-5 MW 17 13 1 2 1 1
5-20 MW 20 20 1 2 1 1
20-50 MW 16 14 1 2 1 1
TOTAL 1-50 MW 53 48 3 6 3 3
Total emission reduction
compared to "no EU action" 45 42 45 45
4.2.4. Overview of pollutant abatement achieved by the emission level options
The table below show a summary of emission reductions achieved in the various abatement level options. It shows that the highest emission reductions -compared to the baseline Option 1- would be achieved for all pollutants under emission level option 7A. While reductions for PM and SO 2 do not substantially differ in the various options, NOx reductions vary considerably. Option 7C would deliver the least reductions for NOx, albeit still in the order of 76 kilotons/year. Option 7D reduces NOx emissions much less than options 7A and 7B but still very significantly: 107 kilotons/year. The additional 20 kilotons/year reduction of option 7D compared to option 7C is due to the stricter ELVs set for new combustion plants, in particular for engines and turbines to comply with the Gothenburg requirements. Option 7E delivers a total NOx reduction of 159 kilotons/year, where additional reduction compared to option 7D are achieved thanks to more stringent NOx emission limit values for new plants.
337
Emission
reduction (kt/y) 2025
Option: 7A 7B 7C 7D 7E
SO2 139 127 127 135 137
NOx 338 288 76 107 159
PM 45 42 42 45 45
4.3. Economic impacts
4.3.1. Compliance costs
To estimate the compliance costs due to the introduction of EU wide emission limit values as under options 7A-7E it was assessed whether additional abatement measures would have to be implemented within the combustion plants concerned compared to the situation without EU action. A set of compliance costs was developed for implementing a range of the most pertinent and applicable abatement measures on the basis of literature data available (Amec, 2013 and references therein). Capital and operational costs have been annualised using default values of a 4% discount rate and an annualisation period of 15 years. A model was applied to automatically identify which abatement measure would be required to achieve the emission levels defined under the different options.
Total costs per Member State were derived from the cost per plant multiplied by the number of plants for each fuel type. The number of plants per fuel type in a Member State was estimated using the percentage fuel mix applied to the total number of plants. When calculating total compliance costs per Member State, account has been taken of the extent to which emissions from medium combustion plants are already regulated under national legislation currently in place. Table A12.9 presents a summary of the average total compliance costs for EU 27 for options 7A-7E for the year 2025.
Table A12.9: Overview of incremental annualised compliance costs (€m/year)
7A: 7C: 7D: 7E:
Pollutant Emission level option: most 7B: Gothenburg SULES
stringent MS LCP
primary NOx
SO 2 1-5 MW 210 90 90 83 100
5-20 MW 123 68 68 72 80
20-50 MW 44 27 27 28 30
TOTAL
1-50 MW 377 185 185 183 210
NO X 1-5 MW 1119 821 27 36 187
5-20 MW 1018 785 18 35 178
20-50 MW 543 311 3 12 91
TOTAL
1-50 MW 2680 1,918 48 83 456
PM 1-5 MW 84 55 55 46 46
5-20 MW 77 41 41 42 45
20-50 MW 77 27 27 28 35
TOTAL
1-50 MW 238 123 123 116 126
TOTAL 1-5 MW 1413 966 171 165 332 5-20 MW 1218 895 127 149 302 20-50 MW 665 365 57 68 156
338
TOTAL
1-50 MW 3296 2226 355 382 790
The table shows that most of the compliance costs under options 7A and 7B are associated with NOx abatement, something that is indeed also reflected also in option 7E, where stringent NOx ELVs are set for new plants.
Option 7C requires combustion modifications but no secondary NOx measures, resulting in drastically lower compliance costs (around 10% of option 7A). The low costs are kept also under option 7D. In this case total compliance costs are only 2% higher than in emission level option 7C and about 12% of the costs under option 7A.
Table A12.10 provides more detail on the distribution of abatement costs between new and existing plants for the different combustion plant types, as studied in options 7D and 7E.
It can be seen that compliance costs for NOx in emission level option 7D are 83M€/year, of which about half of them allocated to new engines and turbines, in particular for the two categories 1-5MW and 5-20MW. Compliance costs for NOx in emission level option 7E rise to 456M€/year, most of them allocated to new boilers, in particular for the two categories 1-5MW and 5-20MW.
In option 7D cost associated to new boilers (7M€) are assumed to be half of those to retrofit existing boilers (13M€). Costs for new engines and turbines (47M€) where secondary measures are taken to comply with Gothenburg requirements are three times higher than for existing engines and turbines where no secondary measures would be required (16M€). In option 7E costs for new boilers are much higher than the one for existing boilers, due the more stringent emission limit values applied.
Table A12.10: Detailed overview of annualised compliance costs for NOx under options 7D and 7E (€m/year)
Figures rounded for presentation purposes (this might lead to minor differences in the totals)
Annualised Category New Existing New engines Existing TOTAL compliance boilers Boilers and turbines engines costs for and NOx turbines (€m/year)
1-5 MW 3 6 19 7 36
Option 7D: 5-20 MW 2 6 21 7 35
Gothenburg 20-50 MW 1 2 7 2 12
TOTAL 1-50 MW 7 13 47 16 83
1-5 MW 148 6 26 7 187
Option 7E:
5-20 MW 138 6 28 7 178
SULE
339
TOTAL 1-50 MW 359 13 68 16 456
For comparison the compliance costs for NOx abatement per new plants in emission level options 7D and 7E are reported in Table A12.11.
Table A12.11: Annualised compliance costs for NOx for new plants under options 7D and 7E (€/plant)
New boilers New engines and turbines
Emission level
option 7D 7E 7D 7E
1-5 MW 140 6000 3100 4200
5-20 MW 440 26800 16000 21700
20-50 MW 1,10 63700 25100 52300
TOTAL 1-50 MW 225 11600 6000 8800
Compliance costs per Member State per emission level option 7D are reported in the tables of Appendix 12.4.
4.3.2. Emission monitoring costs
The introduction of emission limits for MCP also requires setting emission monitoring requirements, which allow verifying compliance with those limits. This involves either the use of on-site monitoring equipment (in case of continuous monitoring) or periodic monitoring by qualified experts using certified monitoring equipment and appropriate standardised sampling, measurement and analytical methods.
Based on a review of available information from existing national legislation as well as the IED requirements for 50-100 MW combustion plants, only periodic monitoring was assumed to be a reasonable option as the costs of continuous monitoring are considered prohibitively high.
The costs of a single emission monitoring campaign are summarised in the Table A12.12.
For this assessment, the monitoring frequency applied for combustion plants in the range 1-20 MW was once per three years and for combustion plants between 20 and 50 MW it was once per year. The resulting total annualised costs for operators are also reported in Table A12.12
340 Table A12.12: Costs of emission monitoring (NOx, SO2 and PM) –per monitoring event and total annualised costs
Costs for operators Per monitoring Annualised costs event * (€) (m€/year)
20-50 MW 7200 4
5-20 MW 4100 6
1-5 MW 2400 15
-
*For natural gas fired plants only NOx monitoring would be required and costs per monitoring event are assumed to be only 50% of the above mentioned costs.
4.3.3. Administrative costs
As described in section 2, MCP can be regulated in different manners in order to ensure that the emission limit values imposed are implemented and complied with. The different regulatory options R1 to R2 differ in the way the administrative procedures for regulating the plants (or broader installations) are set up and hence will result in different administrative costs for both the operators and authorities involved.
Regulatory options R1 and R2
For assessing the administrative costs of those options, the following elements have been considered:
Cost of bringing installations under the regulation: a one-off cost when a permit is granted:
• operators: costs incurred in understanding the legal requirements, preparing applications, responding to requests for information from regulators, etc;
• authorities: costs of producing application materials, consulting the public, determining the application, etc;
Cost of periodic reconsideration of permits: one-off cost when permit is reconsidered;
Ongoing subsistence costs:
• operators: administrative costs (i.e. non-technical) of providing monitoring reports,
accommodating site visits by inspectors, reporting changes in operation, etc;
• authorities: costs of checking compliance, maintaining systems to make information available to the public, updating permit conditions (without amounting to a full reconsideration of the permit), etc;
Soil and groundwater baseline survey: one-off cost at the point of applying for a permit (noting that under this option an integrated approach would apply and not only air emissions would be regulated).
A summary of costs applied for calculating these administrative costs in option R1 is provided in Table 12.13. For the costs of bringing installations under the regulation, periodic reconsideration of permits and annual subsistence costs, these figures are mainly
341
based on the information given in Annex 8 of the European Commission’s Impact
Assessment for the Proposal for a Directive on industrial emissions 53 . The cost data
presented in that impact assessment have been uplifted to 2012 prices from assumed 2006 price levels.
For option R2, where only air emissions are regulated, administrative costs related to other environmental media (e.g. cost for soil & groundwater baseline survey, in Table 12.13) do not occur and have been excluded. As in this option no public participation is foreseen the costs for authorities, presented in Table A12.13, have been reduced by 25% in the calculations.
53 SEC(2007) 1679.
342 Table A12.13: Elements of administrative costs under regulatory Option R1 (Integrated permit) and Option R2 (Emission permit)
(€ per installation unless stated)
Cost of bringing installations under the regulation (one-off)
20-50 MW 23200
Cost for operators 5-20 MW 18500
1-5 MW 13900
20-50 MW 10900
Cost for authorities 5-20 MW 8800
1-5 MW 6600
Cost of periodic reconsideration of permits (one-off)
20-50 MW 2900
Cost for operators 5-20 MW 2300
1-5 MW 1700
20-50 MW 5800
Cost for authorities 5-20 MW 4600
1-5 MW 3500
Annual subsistence costs (ongoing)
20-50 MW 3500
Cost for operators 5-20 MW 2800
1-5 MW 2100
20-50 MW 6900
Cost for authorities 5-20 MW 5600
1-5 MW 4200
Soil & groundwater baseline survey (only option R1)
Cost for operators All 4400 per survey
Regulatory options R3 and R4
Under regulatory options R3 and R4, plant operators would not need to apply for, and maintain, a permit. Therefore, no administrative costs are associated with permit application and reconsideration. Furthermore, as only air emissions would be regulated under these options, administrative costs related to other environmental media would not occur. However, given that notification and some form of periodic emission monitoring would be required, administrative costs associated with preparing, reporting and reviewing of the monitoring reports would be borne by operators and authorities. Therefore for assessing the administrative costs of these options only on-going subsistence costs have been considered. A summary of the cost figures applied under option R3 is given in Table A12.14. These figures are mainly based on the information given in Annex 8 of the European Commission’s Impact Assessment for the Proposal for a Directive on industrial emissions.
343 For option R4, where no notification or register is kept by authorities, the costs have been reduced by 25% with respect to option R3.
344 Table A12.14: Regulatory option R3 (Registration) and R4 (General binding rules): elements of administrative costs
Option R3 Option R4 (€ per installation) (€ per installation)
Annual Subsistence Costs (on-going)
20-50 MW 1800 1350
Cost for operators 5-20 MW 1000 750
1-5 MW 400 300
20-50 MW 2700 2025
Cost for authorities 5-20 MW 1400 1050
1-5 MW 500 375
Total administrative costs
When calculating total administrative costs per Member State based on the above mentioned costs per plant, account has been taken of the extent to which those plants would already be covered by permitting or monitoring regimes under national legislation currently in place. This approach is summarised in Table A12.15. The one-time costs of bringing installations under the regulation, periodic reconsideration of permits and the soil and groundwater baseline survey have been annualised over 20 years.
Table A12.15: Different components of administrative costs included in the assessment
Should the No national National legislation in place Plants
following legislation in With Without which are
administrative place permitting permitting part of IED
costs be applied? installations
Reg. Option R1 and R2 (Permitting)
Yes [1]
Permit Application Yes 50%
Costs 100% option R1 No option R1 No 75% option R2 38%
option R2 Yes Yes
Permit Revision 100% option 100% option
Costs No R1 No R1 75% option 75% option
R2 R2 Yes [1]
Annual Subsistence Yes 50% Costs under a 100% option R1 No option R1 No Permitting Regime 75% option R2 38% option R2 Yes for Yes for Soil & groundwater Yes for option R1 option R1 option R1
baseline survey No for option R2 No for No for No
option R2 option R2 Reg. Option R3 and R4 (without permitting)
345
Should the No national National legislation in place Plants
following legislation in With Without which are
administrative place permitting permitting part of IED
costs be applied? installations
Annual subsistence Yes
costs 100% option R3 No No No 75% option R4
Note [1]: For Member States with national legislation without permitting, permit application costs and subsistence costs under Regulatory Options R1 and R2 were assumed to be 50% less compared to Member States without national legislation. This is taking into consideration that operators and authorities in these Member States with national legislation already incur some level of costs associated with the regulations.
The sum of annualised administrative costs for operators and authorities under the four regulatory options, are provided in Table A12.16.
Table A12.16: Total annualised administrative costs (€m per year, 2012 prices)
Regulatory
option: R1 R2 R3 R4
Operators 1-5 MW 124 67 4 3
5-20 MW 34 20 3 2
20-50 MW 7 3 2 0
TOTAL 1-50
MW 165 90 9 5
Authorities 1-5 MW 104 78 6 5
5-20 MW 31 24 4 3
20-50 MW 9 4 2 1
TOTAL 1-50
MW 144 106 12 9
Total 1-5 MW 228 145 10 8
5-20 MW 65 44 7 5
20-50 MW 16 7 4 1
TOTAL 1-50
MW 309 196 21 14
4.3.4. Total costs
An overview of the total costs (compliance, monitoring, administrative) for operators is presented in Table A12.17, based on the figures from Tables A12.9, A12.12 and A12.16.
The total annualised costs for operators under the different options considered (emission level and regulatory) and their possible combinations range from 385 to 3486 M€.
Total costs in emission level options 7A, 7B and 7E are mainly determined by the compliance costs, while those are much less under options 7C and 7D.
Emission level option 7A would lead to an additional compliance cost in 2025 of nearly 3300 M€/year, which is about 1.5 times higher than option 7B. Under either of these
346 options, more than 80% of costs are associated with NOx abatement measures due to the need to apply secondary measures in a high number of natural gas fired plants.
Total costs for option 7C and 7D, under regulatory options R3 and R4 are comparable and in the order of 400 M€. Under the same regulatory options (R3 and R4), emission level option 7E doubles the total costs to more than 800M€.
347 Table A12.17: Total annualised costs for operators (€m/year, figures rounded for presentation purposes)
Capacity Year 2025
Ambition
level option: Option 7A: most stringent MS Option 7B: LCP Option 7C: primary NOx Option 7D: Gothenburg Option 7E: SULES
Regulatory R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4
option:
1-5 MW Admin cost 124 67 4 3 124 67 4 3 124 67 4 3 124 67 4 3 124 67 4 3
Monitoring
cost 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15
Compliance
cost 1413 1413 1413 1413 966 966 966 966 171 171 171 171 165 165 165 165 332 332 332 332
Total cost 1552 1495 1432 1431 1105 1048 985 984 310 253 190 189 304 247 184 183 471 414 351 350
5-20 MW Admin cost 34 20 3 2 34 20 3 2 34 20 3 2 34 20 3 2 34 20 3 2
Monitoring
cost 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6
Compliance
cost 1218 1218 1218 1218 895 895 895 895 127 127 127 127 149 149 149 149 302 302 302 302
Total cost 1258 1244 1227 1226 935 921 904 903 167 153 136 135 189 175 158 157 342 328 311 310
20-50 MW Admin cost 7 3 2 0 7 3 2 0 7 3 2 0 7 3 2 0 7 3 2 0
Monitoring
cost 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4
Compliance
cost 665 665 665 665 365 365 365 365 57 57 57 57 68 68 68 68 156 156 156 156
Total cost 676 672 671 669 376 372 371 369 68 64 63 61 79 75 74 72 167 163 162 160
Admin cost 165 90 9 5 165 90 9 5 165 90 9 5 165 90 9 5 165 90 9 5
TOTAL 1-50 MW Monitoring cost 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25
Compliance
cost 3296 3296 3296 3296 2226 2226 2226 2226 355 355 355 355 382 382 382 382 790 790 790 790
Total cost 3486 3411 3330 3326 2416 2341 2260 2256 545 470 389 385 572 497 416 412 980 905 824 820
348 349
Whilst the integrated permitting option results in administrative costs of 165
M€/year, this is strongly reduced under the "lighter" regulatory options. A system of notification/registration and common rules under option R3 would allow reducing the administrative burden from avoided permit application costs, and the benefits of a standardised approach replacing permit conditions that vary from one authority to another.
Although the regulatory options considered do not have a direct environmental impact, the requirement under regulatory options R1 and R2 for each plant to have a permit would allow the consideration of the need for stricter conditions in order to ensure compliance with local air quality standards.
Also, concerning the regulatory options without a permit, option R3 would allow mapping emissions of medium size plant and therefore improving knowledge and emission inventories, which would not be possible with option R4.
4.3.5. Impacts on small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs)
Data gathered from consultations with stakeholders indicates that about 75% of the MCP can be assumed to be operated within SMEs (about 53% in small and 23% in medium size enterprises). This varies between around 50% for 20-50
MW plants to more than 80% of 5-20 MW plants 54 .
The direct economic impacts of potential legislation on SMEs can be assessed by comparing the total costs incurred per plant against the level of financial resources available to the operator for investment. Information available in Eurostat Structural Business Statistics includes gross operating surplus (GOS), which is the capital available to companies which allows them to repay their
creditors, to pay taxes and eventually to finance all or part of their investment 55 .
Considering that GOS can be used for financing investment, an indication of the economic impact is given by comparing the costs per plant against GOS per operator.
An assessment of the extent to which SMEs might be affected has been performed combining the sectorial distribution data gathered from consultations with stakeholders with the sectorial enterprise size data from Eurostat.
An indication of the total annual cost per enterprise as a proportion of GOS is given in Table A12.18.
54 For those sectors where Eurostat provides enterprise size categories, it is extremely unlikely that the
sector-wide average proportion of micro-size enterprises (i.e. 71% to 94%) would be observed for 1-50 MW combustion plants. It is anticipated that this high proportion of micro enterprises relate to much smaller combustion plants (i.e. <1 MW) which are outside of the scope of the options considered in this study although some might operate in the smallest capacity class considered (i.e. 1-5 MW). Furthermore, in a number of cases, such combustion plants are typically a part of a bigger complex requiring more than 9 employees to maintain and operate, and therefore it is highly unlikely that any micro-size enterprises would operate them
350 In general, the economic impact on SMEs respect to GOS varies from 0.1 to 22%, depending on the option chosen and the size category of the plant.
High impacts, in the order of 10%, are incurred by small enterprises for all regulatory options and emission level options 7A and 7B and raise to 20% for small enterprises operating a MCP in the category 20-50MW if emission level 7A is chosen.
For options 7C and 7D the impacts ranges from 0.1% to 2.5%, the highest figure again for small enterprises operating an MCP in the category 20-50MW. It is assumed that about 35% of MCPs in the 20-50MW category are run by small enterprises.
It should be noted that as explained under the description of the regulatory options [see section 2], several simplified requirements intentionally based on an approach entailing simplified permitting/registration (with respect, for instance, to requirements set in the Industrial Emission Directive) have been already taken into account in their design. In addition, the options considered in relation to emission monitoring and reporting have also been moderated, in view of the high number of SMEs concerned.
Additional mitigation measures aiming to further reduce economic impacts on SMEs under the various options have been also investigated. Several potential mitigating measures implemented in EU legislation have been identified and are in the section below.
351 Table A12.18: Total annual cost per enterprise as a proportion (%) of GOS
Emission
2025 level 7A: most stringent 7B: LCP 7C: primary 7D:Gothenburg 7E:SULES option: MS NOx
Enterprise size Regulatory
option: R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4 R1 R2 R3 R4
1-5 MW 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.6 2.0 1.9 1.8 1.8 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.6 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.6
Small 5-20 MW 13.7 13.6 13.4 13.4 10.2 10.0 9.9 9.9 1.8 1.7 1.5 1.5 2.1 1.9 1.7 1.7 3.7 3.6 3.4 3.4
20-50 MW 21.7 21.5 21.5 21.4 12.0 11.9 11.9 11.8 2.2 2.1 2.0 2.0 2.5 2.4 2.4 2.3 5.3 5.2 5.2 5.1
1-5 MW 0.7 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2
Medium 5-20 MW 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7
20-50 MW 5.5 5.5 5.5 5.5 3.1 3.0 3.0 3.0 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.3
352
4.3.6. Measures to mitigate impacts on SMEs
The Commission’s 2013 Communication on Smart Regulation – Responding to the
needs of small and medium-sized enterprises 56 recognises that it may not always be
possible or desirable to provide exemptions or lighter requirements for particular types of enterprises (including SMEs): “It is acknowledged by SMEs and their representatives that SMEs cannot expect to be above the law. [...]Exemptions or lighter provisions for smaller businesses will not undermine overall public policy objectives pursued through the relevant regulations, for example in public and workplace health and safety, food safety or environmental protection.” [extract from COM(2013) 122 final i]
The pollutants addressed in this impact assessment are mainly health related and location specific and providing blanket exemptions or derogations would work against the objectives of this legislative measure. Therefore, mitigation measures are examined with a view to identify those that would reduce the financial and administrative burden on SMEs whilst not running counter to the set objectives of the specific policy, and being enforceable at a reasonable cost.
4.3.6.1. Phased implementation
Phased implementation with a longer lead-in time for some companies can allow such companies more time to adapt and align their compliance actions with their ‘normal’ investment cycle. The IED (and its predecessors e.g. IPPC and LCP Directives) contain phased implementation requirements for existing installations in order to give those already in operation sufficient time to make the necessary upgrades and comply with their permits. Under this approach, the compliance costs are slightly reduced as companies have more scope to integrate achieving compliance into their investment cycle. Specifically, a lower proportion of older plants would be rendered prematurely obsolete as a result of the regulatory change. The eventual benefits would be unchanged on a per annum basis, but would be reduced overall due to the delay in accruing them. There is a slight risk with such an approach in that some operators may subsequently hold off replacing an existing plant with a new one thus reducing the overall benefits in the short term (i.e. they may choose to run their existing plant up to the deadline for compliance before replacing it) but the longer term benefits would be the same and a phased implementation should reduce overall economic impacts.
4.3.6.2. Sectoral exemptions or derogations
The main existing policy in which sectoral exemptions and derogations have been
applied is the EU Emissions Trading System 57 (EU ETS). Industries covered by the
EU ETS, which are deemed to be exposed to a significant risk of 'carbon leakage' receive a higher share of free allowances in the third trading period between 2013 and 2020. The EU ETS establishes a complex methodology for determining such sectors, where the criteria are based on percent of costs incurred by the sector respect to its gross added value (GVA) or the intensity of trade respect to third countries. It also establishes that a list of sectors at risk should be drawn up and
57 Directive 2009/29/EC i, previously Directive 2003/87/EC i.
353 revised every three years. The first carbon leakage list was adopted by the Commission at the end of 2009 and amended in 2011 and 2012. These exemptions do not affect the environmental effectiveness of the EU ETS (which is determined by the overall cap) although they reduce the cost burden on certain sectors.
Any analogous approach for air pollutants emitted from MCP would however affect health and environmental impacts, because the only feasible sectoral approach would be to exempt specific sectors from the scope of the policy altogether. Measures have already been assessed regarding the implementation costs for all plant as a proportion of GOS, which provides a basis to reduce the burden. However there are no identifiable sectors for which the residual impact is
particularly high 58 . Also given the much smaller economic impact of the MCP
compared with the EU ETS, further measures on sectoral exemption would be disproportionate.
4.3.6.3. Size-related exemptions and derogations
The regulatory burden on SMEs can be lightened via exemptions or derogations for specific enterprises on the basis of their number of employees, turnover and/or
balance sheet 59 . This could apply to the smallest (i.e. micro) enterprises only or
include others within the SME definition. The Commission’s 2013 Communication on Smart Regulation – Responding to the needs of small and medium-sized
enterprises 60 identifies some examples of SME exemptions that have been proposed
by the Commission and are now in the EU legislative procedure. The challenge for following this approach is that for MCPs the burden of costs are often shared between the owner of the MCP that may be a separate company to its operator. Given the significant variation in such shared set-ups across the EU, any attempts to separate out SME’s from larger enterprises may inadvertently reduce the costeffectiveness of the policy tool.
Micro-enterprises are extremely unlikely to be affected given that MCPs would normally not be operated by enterprises of very small size.
4.3.6.4. Exemptions or derogations based on operating hours and/or emissions
Softening the regulatory burden on specific companies is also possible via exemptions or derogations on the basis of metrics such as activity, product specifications, environmental impact indicators and the like. While this approach does not specifically target SMEs, the benefits of the exemption would be most relevant for those companies with the least resources available to shoulder any potential increase in regulatory burden, a category which is deemed more likely to include a higher proportion of SMEs (relative to the category of larger companies). For the policy options under consideration, a possible starting point would be current Member State legislation in the field. For instance, a number of Member
58 Option 7D couple with regulatory option R3 would have an impact on SMEs that ranges from 0.1% to
max 2.5% of GOS. In the case of EU ETS 'a sector is deemed to be exposed to a significant risk of carbon leakage when additional costs induced by the implementation of the directive would lead to a substantial increase of production costs, calculated as a proportion of GVA of at least 5%'.
59 In line with the SME definitions provided in Recommendation (2003/361/EC).
354
States have legislation in place covering combustion plants below 50 MW that exempt plants if they operate a low number of hours (e.g. <300 hours per year). The aim of this is to exempt back-up and emergency plants from having to make costly upgrades (and incurring administrative burden) with limited environmental benefit. Exempting plants with low operating hours and/or low overall emissions would have the potential to substantially reduce overall costs without impacting as much on the overall benefits. In order to assuring that any potential health benefits are safeguarded less strict measures could be still required for certain pollutants (e.g. less strict ELVs for PM).
Based on data provided by the Member States, 10-25% of MCP operates less than 300 hours per year. The analysis assumes, therefore, that 17.5% of plants (midpoint of the range 10-25%) would be exempted. This results in a reduction in costs in equal proportion (17,5%), while emissions are estimated to increase by only 1% due to the low number of operating hours.
4.3.6.5. Financial support
Reducing disproportionate burden on SMEs, while safeguarding delivering the policy objectives may also be achieved through the provision by Member States of financial support to particular companies (e.g. SMEs), in order to help meet the regulatory requirements. Such financial support may be direct (e.g. loans or support schemes) or indirect (e.g. reduced fees). Under these approaches, compliance costs for SMEs would be reduced, with no impact on benefits. Costs to Member States through the provision of financial support would be higher, depending on the specific support measures adopted.
4.3.6.6. Non-financial support
Support could be provided by the Commission and/or Member States in the form of guidance, template application/reporting forms and/or help desks to help companies understand how to comply with regulatory requirements and to make decisions on what actions are necessary. It might be possible and helpful to establish an approved abatement technology supplier list that companies could easily consult e.g. via a dedicated website. While not explicitly targeting SMEs, it is expected that SMEs would benefit most from such support, as they have fewer resources at their disposal to understand and implement new regulatory requirements. This approach would slightly reduce the transaction costs companies incur to meet the regulatory requirements, although it would entail some costs for competent authorities and/or the Commission (depending on who produced, delivered and administered the support scheme). The environmental benefits would be likely to increase slightly as regulatory compliance rates would increase and companies could possibly implement the necessary changes sooner.
4.3.6.7. Conclusion on mitigation measures
The mitigation measures selected as appropriate for a regulatory measure to control air pollutant emissions from MCP are listed in Table A12.19; where action would be at EU level these measures have been integrated in the design of certain policy options.
355 Table A12.19: Selected mitigation measures
Mitigation measure Description
Included in options 7D and 7E: Phased implementation New plants need to comply with set ELVs as of 2018,
existing in 2022.
Derogations for existing Included in options 7D and 7E:
installations ELVs for new plants are set stricter than the one for existing plants.
Included in options 7D and 7E: Exemptions or derogations Exemption for existing combustion plants which do based on operating hours not operate more than 300 hours per year (for PM
emission an upper “safeguard” limit could be set). Included in options R2, R3, R4:
Simplified permitting and Option R2 takes into consideration a light permitting
reporting obligations regime, while no permit but only registration is considered in option R3 and simply notification under
option R4. Included in options (R1 to R4): Lighter monitoring requirements than those set in the Industrial Emission Directive are considered for all
Simplified monitoring the options (R1 to R4). obligations In all the options (R1 to R4) lighter monitoring
requirements are set for the smaller plants: every three years for plants in the categories 1-5 and 5-20MW, annually for 20-50 MW plants.
Financial and non Financial and non-financial support could be financial support envisaged by Member State.
4.3.7. Impacts on intra-EU competition
Analysis of possible effects on competition (principally within the EU) of the various options shows that the overall effect of the additional costs on competition within and between sectors is relatively modest. This is because of the general applicability of the options, which bring the requirements for MCP more in line with those already imposed on larger installations. Clearly the absolute impacts would differ under the various options, i.e. depending on the levels at which ELVs are established and the regulatory approach taken. However, all of the options should have only very limited effects on liberalisation rules, no significant effect increasing barriers to entry and no effect on commercial rights. There is no one dominant supplier or dominant approach across the installations concerned. It is not envisaged that the options considered would impact on sectoral rules, unless specific exemptions were proposed. Neither option would appear to interfere with existing rules or corporate law. Member States will be affected in a similar way and base assumption would be that starting from the same level each country’s average
356 cost would be approximately the same, and that the differences are largely attributable to levelling up from a low base rather than any intrinsic country effect.
4.3.8. Impacts on international competitiveness, trade, and investment flows
The majority of MCP are used in local contexts meeting local heat and/or energy needs and those are unlikely to directly face international competition. There could be however some significant impact on competitiveness for certain industry sectors, particularly food and drink manufacturers and the greenhouse sector. These sectors face stiff competition from outside the EU. It is likely that at least a sub set of these users will have difficulty in passing on costs to their current markets and in the case of greenhouses there are well established competitors ready to compete from outside the EU. In food production the increasing commoditisation of the industry creates pressures for some producers and increases in costs will be difficult to pass on. Possible mitigation could focus on actions targeted at those specific sectors and are likely to be similar to the measures considered for reducing impacts on SMEs. Applying exemptions to those sectors / uses facing the greatest international competition could be an option and although quality and product differentiation may protect food and industry from some of the competition those arguments may be harder to make for greenhouses which compete with areas with abundant sunshine and warmth.
4.4. Social Impacts
The implementation of the proposed MCP instrument on the one hand will lead to costs for the companies that need to invest in pollution abatement equipment, but on the other hand generates income for the firms that manufacture and install the same equipment. The EU has a well-established abatement technology supply chain as the majority of the technologies currently being applied by larger combustion plants are also relevant for these smaller plants.
Where firms are able to pass on costs to downstream consumers, the additional production costs can be expected to have a small negative effect on real income through raising aggregate price levels, resulting in a reduction in consumption and consequently in employment.
Although general equilibrium effects may tip the balance one side or the other, a reasonable assumption is that that the overall effect would be fairly neutral.
It is acknowledged that certain specific sectors such as the food and drink sector and greenhouses, that find it difficult to pass on costs to consumers in light of international competition, could be adversely affected resulting in a reduction of production and, therefore, employment within the EU.
357 5. C OMPARISON OF POLICY OPTIONS AND SELECTION OF PREFERRED
OPTION
The comparison of options is based on qualitative or quantitative criteria related to the effectiveness, the efficiency and coherence in achieving the specific objectives defined in section 4.3 of the impact assessment, as follows:
-
1.Effectiveness:
o Emission reduction;
-
2.Efficiency:
o Pollutant abatement cost;
-
3.Coherence:
o EU compliance with international obligations; o Administrative costs; Impacts on SMEs.
5.1. Emission reduction
The emission reductions of the options compared with "no EU action" in 2025 are (kt/y):
Option: 7A 7B 7C 7D 7E
SO2 139 127 127 135 137
NOx 338 288 76 107 159
PM 45 42 42 45 45
All options have the potential to make a substantial contribution to reducing the emission of
pollutants.
5.2. Pollutant abatement cost
Table A12.20 summarises the pollutant abatement cost (€/t of pollutant reduced) for the five emission level options 7A-7E. The average abatement cost is calculated as the compliance cost divided by the associated emission reduction for each pollutant. This is compared to the range of damage costs avoided by reducing the same emissions (EMRC 2013, to be published). This shows that the abatement costs compare favourably with the damage costs under all options except for NOx where only options 7C, 7D and 7E are favourable from a cost-benefit perspective.
Table A12.20: Removal costs and avoided damage costs (€/t)
Abatement cost per ton of pollutant reduced (€/t) Damage costs (€/t)
Emission
level 7A 7B 7C 7D 7E
option:
358
Abatement cost per ton of pollutant reduced (€/t) Damage costs (€/t)
Emission
level 7A 7B 7C 7D 7E
option:
SO2 2600 1400 1400 1400 1500 7600 – 21200
PM 5200 2900 2900 2500 2800 14750-41650*
NO X 7600 6300 500 800 2,900 5500-13900
-
*To allow comparison in this table, damage costs for PM2.5 (29500-83300€/t) have been reduced by half to account for the complex relationship between PM and PM2.5 (see footnote 1 to section 1.3 of this annex)
However, the costs associated to option 7E have a high sensitivity to the reference date chosen. Whereas for options 7A to 7D the costs for 2025 and 2030 are very close, this is not the case for option 7E where very stringent standards apply to new plants and costs increase with the rate of replacement of existing plants by new plants. In 2025 it is assumed that 27% of the plants will have been replaced; further replacement of existing plants by new plants after 2025 would entail significant additional NOx abatement costs in the order of 200-300€/ton per boiler and 3,900€/ton per engine or turbine.
5.3. EU compliance with international obligations
Out of the three options 7C, 7D and 7E that have the most favourable cost-benefit profile both options 7D and 7E allow the EU to fully comply with its international obligations under the Gothenburg Protocol. Option C does not allow such compliance for certain types of engines.
5.4. Administrative costs
The choice of the regulatory option has a limited impact on the cost-benefit ratio but is an important driver for administrative costs. The requirement under regulatory options R1 and R2 for each plant to have a permit would lead to higher administrative costs representing 18-29% of total costs but would also allow the consideration of the need for stricter conditions in order to ensure compliance with local air quality standards. Administrative costs are significantly lower for R3 (registration) and R4 (general binding rules) representing 1-2% of total costs. Unlike option R4, option R3 would allow mapping emissions of medium size plant and therefore improving knowledge and emission inventories.
5.5. Impacts on SMEs
By combining the emission level of options 7C or 7D having the most favourable cost-benefit profile with the low administrative cost regulatory options R3 or R4 the impact on SMEs are limited to 0.1 – 2.4% of the GOS. With emission level option 7E the impact on SMEs would reach 0.2 - 5.2% of GOS.
359 5.6. Option comparision summary
The comparison of options for each of the identified topic areas is based on qualitative criteria related to the effectiveness, the efficiency and coherence in achieving the specific objectives defined in section 4.3 of the impact assessment. The ratings applied are no effect (0), low (L), medium (M), high (H) and not applicable (NA).
7A 7B 7C 7D 7E R1-R2 R3-R4
Effectiveness H H H H H NA NA
Efficiency L H H H M NA NA
Coherence L L M H M L H
The more detailed breakdown for the three criteria used to assess coherence is:
7A 7B 7C 7D 7E R1-R2 R3-R4
Administrative
costs NA NA NA NA NA L H
EU compliance with international H L L H H
obligations NA NA
Impacts on SMEs L L H H L L H
In addition, unlike option R4, option R3 would allow mapping emissions of medium combustion plants and therefore improving knowledge and emission inventories, which would facilitate policy evaluation.
A summary table, showing the baseline and impacts of the options in 2025 is presented below (figures refer to regulatory option R3)
No EU action Baseline 2025
SO2 emissions (kt/y) 174
NOx emissions (kt/y) 455
PM emissions in (kt/y) 48
Impact of policy options: emissions 7A 7B 7C 7D 7E
SO2 emission reduction
(kt/y) 139 127 127 135 (79)
• 137
NOx emission reduction
(kt/y) 338 288 76
107
(108) • 159
360
PM* emission reduction
(kt/y) 45 42 42 45 (26)
• 45
Impact of policy options: costs 7A 7B 7C 7D 7E
Compliance costs for
operators (M€/y) 3296 2226 355 382 790
Impact of policy options: total annual cost per enterprise as a proportion (%) of GOS 7A 7B 7C 7D 7E
1-5 MW 2.6 1.8 0.3 0.3 0.6 Small
enterprises 5-20 MW 13.4 9.9 1.5 1.7 3.4
20-50 MW 21.5 11.9 2.0 2.4 5.2
1-5 MW 0.6 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.2 Medium
enterprises 5-20 MW 2.7 2.0 0.3 0.3 0.7
20-50 MW 5.5 3.0 0.5 0.6 1.3
*for technical reasons this is expressed as total particulate matter; to be divided by a factor 2 to convert to PM2.5
Number in brackets (xx) • are calculated by IIASA 6C*, PM emission have been multiplied by a factor
2 to convert from PM2.5
5.7. Preferred option
The comparison indicates that the most favourable approach is emission level option 7D combined with regulatory option R3. This has a very favourable costbenefit profile, combines low compliance costs with low administrative costs, allows the EU to fully comply with its international obligations, and limits the economic impacts on SMEs. This combination also incorporates the mitigation measures selected in section 3.3.6.7.
Whilst options 7D and R3 come out as most favourable for taking action at EU level, in particular situations such as for instance air quality management zones in non-compliance with the AAQD limit values, Members States and local authorities might need to adopt stricter abatement measures, such as those reflected in the emission level option 7E.
-
6.M ONITORING AND EVALUATION
Monitoring of the implementation and impact of measures on MCP will be based on streamlined and targeted reporting requirements on the Member States focusing on the key data which are necessary to assess the extent to which the objectives of the legislation are being achieved. The Commission will evaluate the results of this policy in 2023. On that basis the legislation will be revised as necessary.
The following indicators will be monitored:
361
Objective Indicator How Responsible Reporting/review monitored/calculated authority
Emission Sectoral Reporting of national Designated MS interim reductions from emissions of emission totals from MCP national reporting in tri MCP SO2, NOx, PM estimated on the basis of authorities annual reporting in
plant registrations (reported by the 2020 MS)
Review in 2023 based on MS implementation reports
362
A PPENDIX 12.1 E MISSION V ALUES FOR THE DIFFERENT OPTIONS
Emission values used for options 7A, 7B,and 7C
Option Rated SO 3 3 3 2 (mg/Nm ) NO X (mg/Nm ) PM (mg/Nm ) thermal
input Solid Other Liquid Other Solid Other Liquid Natural Other Solid Other Liquid
(MW) Biomass solid fuel gaseous Biomass solid fuel gas gaseous Biomass solid fuel
fuel fuel fuel fuel fuel
Boilers (reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of biomass and other solid fuels)
Option 1-5 200 200 200 5 200 100 120 70 150 8 50 5 7A 5-20 200 200 200 5 145 100 120 70 164 5 20 5 Most
stringent 20-50 200 200 200 5 145 100 120 70 164 5 20 5
MS
Option 1-5 200 400 350 35 300 300 450 100 200 30 30 30 7B: 5-20 200 400 350 35 300 300 450 100 200 30 30 30 LCP
20-50 200 400 350 35 300 300 450 100 200 30 30 30
Option 1-5 200 400 350 35 700 880 650 290 290 30 30 30 7C: 5-20 200 400 350 35 680 680 630 280 280 30 30 30 Primary NOx 20-50 200 400 350 35 680 680 490 490 250 30 30 30
Engines and turbines (reference oxygen content: 15%)
Option 1-5 - - 200 5 - - 46 33 48 - - 3 7A 5-20 - - 200 5 - - 46 33 33 - - 3 Most stringent 20-50 - - 200 5 - - 46 33 33 - - 3 MS
Option 1-5 - - 350 35 - - 450 75 110 - - 30 7B: 5-20 - - 350 35 - - 450 75 110 - - 30 LCP
20-50 - - 350 35 - - 450 75 110 - - 30
Option 1-5 - - 350 35 - - 470 250 210 - - 30 7C: 5-20 - - 350 35 - - 560 250 210 - - 30 Primary NOx 20-50 - - 350 35 - - 430 310 250 - - 30
363
Emission values used for option 7D
SO 2 (mg/Nm 3 ) existing combustion plants
Boilers (reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of solid fuels)
Rated SO 3 2 (mg/Nm ) thermal input Solid Other Other liquid fuels Heavy Fuel Oil Gaseous (MW) Biomass solid than HFO (HFO) fuels other than natural gas fuels
1<50 200 400 170 350 35
Engines and gas turbines (reference oxygen content: 15%)
Rated SO 3 2 (mg/Nm ) thermal input Liquid fuels Gaseous (MW) fuels other than natural gas
1<50 - - 60 15
NOx (mg/Nm3) existing combustion plants
Boilers (reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of solid fuels)
Rated NO 3 X (mg/Nm ) thermal input Solid Other Other liquid fuels Heavy Fuel Oil Natural Gaseous (MW) Biomass solid than HFO (HFO) gas fuels other fuel than natural gas
1 - <50 650 650 200 650 200 250
Engines and gas turbines (reference oxygen content: 15%)
Rated NO X (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Liquid fuels Natural Gaseous (MW) gas fuels other than natural gas
Gas 1<50 - - - 190 190 Engines
Diesel 1<50 1,850 (construction commenced before - - Engines 17 May 2006)
190 (construction commenced on or after 18 May 2006)
Dual 1<50 1,850 380 380 fuel engines
Gas 1<50 200 150 200 turbines
364
PM (mg/Nm3) existing combustion plants
Boilers (reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of solid fuels)
Rated PM (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Solid Other Other liquid fuels Heavy Fuel Oil (MW) Biomass solid than HFO (HFO) fuels
1<50 30 30 30 30 -
Engines and gas turbines (reference oxygen content: 15%)
Rated PM (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Liquid fuels (MW)
1<50 - - 10 -
SO2 (mg/Nm3) new combustion plants
Boilers (reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of solid fuels)
Rated SO 2 (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Solid Other Other liquid fuels Heavy Fuel Oil Gaseous (MW) Biomass solid than HFO (HFO) fuels other than natural gas fuels
1<50 200 400 170 350 35
Engines and gas turbines (reference oxygen content: 15%)
Rated SO 2 (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Liquid fuels Gaseous (MW) fuels other than natural gas
1<50 - - 60 15
365
NOx (mg/Nm3) new combustion plants
Boilers (reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of solid fuels)
Rated NO X (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Solid Other Other liquid fuels Heavy Fuel Oil Natural Gaseous (MW) Biomass solid than HFO (HFO) gas fuels other fuel than natural gas
1 - <50 300 300 200 300 100 200
Engines and gas turbines (reference oxygen content: 15%)
Rated NO X (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Liquid fuel Natural Gaseous (MW) gas fuels other than natural gas
Gas, 1<50 - - 190 95 190 Dual Fuel and Diesel Engines
Gas 1<50 75 50 75 turbines
PM (mg/Nm3) new combustion plants
Boilers (reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of solid fuels)
Rated PM (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Solid Other Liquid fuels (MW) Biomass solid fuels
1<50 20 20 20 -
Engines and gas turbines (reference oxygen content: 15%)
Rated PM (mg/Nm 3 ) thermal input Liquid fuels (MW)
1<50 - - 10 -
366
Emission values used for option 7E
(emission values for existing plants are the same as for option 7D)
Rated SO 2 (mg/Nm 3 ) NO X (mg/Nm 3 ) particulate matter therma (mg/Nm 3 )
l input (MW) Solid Coal, Liqui Gaseou Solid Coal, Liqui Natura Gaseou Solid Coal, Liqui Biomas lignit d s Biomas lignit d l s Biomas lignit d s e and fuel fuel s e and fuel gas fuel s e and fuel other other other other other solid than solid than solid fuel natural fuel natural fuel gas gas
Combustion plants other than engines and gas turbines
(reference oxygen content: 3% in case of gaseous and liquid fuels and 6% in case of solid biomass, coal, lignite and other solid fuels)
1-5 200 70 8 5
5-20 150 200 200 5 100 120 70 5 145 70 5 5
20-50
Engines and gas turbines
(reference oxygen content: 15%)
1-50 - 60 2 - 46 33 33 3
367
A PPENDIX 12.2 E MISSION FOR 2025 AND 2030 FOR OPTIONS 7A, 7B AND 7C.
SO2 emissions (kt/year)
2010 2025 2030
Emission 1: 7B: 7A: 1: 7B: 7A: level option: No EU LCP most No EU LCP most action stringent action stringent MS MS 1-5 MW 103 58 13 9 56 12 9 5-20 MW 130 67 17 12 65 16 12 20-50 MW 68 49 17 14 45 15 13 TOTAL 1-50 301 174 47 35 166 44 34 MW
NOx emissions (kt/year)
2010 2025 2030
Emission level 1: 7C: 7B: 7A: 1: 7C: 7B: 7A: option: no primary LCP most no primary LCP most
EU NOx stringent EU NOx stringent action MS action MS 1-5 MW 210 170 140 63 46 175 136 61 45
5-20 MW 227 188 149 62 47 192 147 61 47 20-50 MW 117 98 90 42 24 97 89 41 24
TOTAL
1-50 MW 554 455 379 167 117 463 372 163 116
PM emissions (kt/year)
2010 2025 2030
1: 7B: 7A: 1: 7B: 7A: Emission level No EU LCP most No EU LCP most option: action stringent action stringent
MS MS
1-5 MW 17 13 2 1 16 2 1
5-20 MW 20 20 2 1 19 2 1
20-50 16 15 2 1 13 2 1 MW
TOTAL 53 48 6 3 48 6 3 1-50 MW
368
A PPENDIX 12.3 O VERVIEW OF ANNUALISED COMPLIANCE COSTS (€ M / YEAR ) UNDER OPTIONS 7C, 7B AND 7A ( INCREMENTAL COSTS TO OPTION 1)
Pollutan Capacity
t class 2025 2030
7C: 7B: 7A: 7C: 7B: 7A: Emissio
n level primar LCP most primar LCP most
option: y NOx stringen y NOx stringen t MS t MS
SO 2 1-5 MW 90 90 210 86 86 188
5-20
MW 68 68 123 64 64 113
20-50
MW 27 27 44 25 25 40
TOTAL 1-50 185 185 377 174 174 341 MW
NO X 1-5 MW 27 821 1,119 27 811 1,075
5-20
MW 18 785 1,018 18 773 994
20-50
MW 3 311 543 3 314 534
TOTAL 1,91
1-50 48 8 2,680 48
1,89
8 2,603
MW
PM 1-5 MW 55 55 84 53 53 82
5-20
MW 41 41 77 41 41 75
20-50
MW 27 27 77 26 26 75
TOTAL
1-50 123 123 239 121 121 232
MW
Total 1-5 MW 171 966 1,413 166 950 1,345
5-20
MW 127 895 1,218 123 878 1,183
20-50
MW 57 365 665 54 365 649
TOTAL 2,19
1-50 355
2,22
5 3,296 343 3 3,176
MW
369
A PPENDIX 12.4 A NNUALISED COMPLIANCE COSTS (€ M / YEAR ) PER M EMBER S TATE UNDER OPTION 7D
SO 2 NOx
compliance compliance PM compliance costs TOTAL Option 7D costs TOTAL 1- Option 7D costs TOTAL 1- Option 7D
1-50 MW 50 MW 2025 50 MW 2025 2025
(€m/yr) (€m/yr) (€m/yr)
AT 5,3 AT 0,7 AT 0,5
BE 7,8 BE 5,9 BE 4,8
BG 1,4 BG 3,7 BG 3,7
CY 0,6 CY 0,1 CY 0,2
CZ 3,4 CZ 0,3 CZ 2,1
DE 63,9 DE 13,9 DE 18,8
DK 9,6 DK 4,0 DK 8,9
EE 4,7 EE 0,5 EE 2,9
EL 0,2 EL 0,4 EL 0,3
ES 8,1 ES 8,2 ES 6,4
FI 2,8 FI 0,9 FI 1,9
FR 29,0 FR 9,2 FR 18,2
HU 3,5 HU 2,8 HU 2,2
IE 10,0 IE 3,1 IE 8,6
IT 2,4 IT 7,0 IT 1,2
LT 3,5 LT 1,5 LT 2,2
LU - LU 0,2 LU -
LV 0,9 LV 0,8 LV 3,8
MT 0,1 MT - MT -
NL - NL 0,4 NL 0,1
PL 13,8 PL 1,9 PL 9,2
PT 2,3 PT 0,7 PT 3,6
RO 2,6 RO 2,6 RO 4,0
SE 2,2 SE 2,7 SE 5,9
SI 0,1 SI 0,9 SI 1,2
SK 0,2 SK 0,4 SK 2,3
UK 4,6 UK 10,6 UK 2,6
370
ANNEX 13 R EFERENCES
AEA, 2005. Damages per tonne emission of PM2.5, NH3, SO2, NOx and VOCs from each
EU25 Member State (excluding Cyprus) and surrounding seas. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/archives/cafe/activities/pdf/cafe_cba_externalities .pdf
AEA, 2008. Analysis of the Costs and Benefits of Proposed Revisions to the National Emission Ceilings Directive. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pollutants/pdf/necd_cba_3.pdf
AEAT, 2007. Assessment of the benefits and costs of the potential application of the IPPC Directive (EC/96/61) to industrial combustion installations with 20-50 MW rated thermal input. Final Report to the European Commission. http://www.cafe-cba.org/assets/ippc_ec_thernal_input.pdf
AMEC, 2012A. Collection and analysis of data to support the Commission in reporting in line with Article 73(2)(a) of Directive 2010/75 i/EU on industrial emissions on the need to control emissions from the combustion of fuels in installations with a total rated thermal input below 50 MW. Final Report for the European Commission.
AMEC, 2012B. Analysis and summary of the Member States' emission inventories 2007-2009 and related information under the LCP Directive (2001/80/EC). Final Report for the European Commission.
AMEC, 2013. Analysis of the impacts of various options to control emissions from the combustion of fuels in installations with a total rated thermal input below 50. To be published.
Compassion in World Farming, 2012. Egg production in the EU - Information sheet. http://www.compassionlebensmittelwirtschaft.de/wpcontent/uploads/2012/05/Info-1-Egg-production-in-the-EU.pdf.pdf
CSES, 2013. Fitness Check of the Legal Framework for the Type-Approval of Motor Vehicles. http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/sectors/automotive/files/projects/report-cses-fitnesscheck_en.pdf
Danish Ministry of the Environment, 2012. Economic Impact Assessment for the establishment of a NECA in the North Sea, Environmental Project no. 1427. http://www2.mst.dk/Udgiv/publications/2012/06/978-87-92903-20-4.pdf
371 EC, 2006. Competitiveness of the European Food Industry: An Economic and Legal Assessment 2007. http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/sectors/food/files/competitiveness_study_en.pdf
EC, 2011. Prospects for Agricultural Markets and Income in the EU 2011-2020. http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/publi/caprep/prospects2011/fullrep_en.pdf
EC, 2012A. Consultation on options for revision of the EU Thematic Strategy on
Air Pollution and related policies. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/consultations/air_pollution_en.htm
EC, 2012B. Prospects for Agricultural Markets and Income in the EU 2012-2022. http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/publi/caprep/prospects2012/fullrep_en.pdf
ECN, 2008. Onderbouwing actualisatie BEES B: Kosten en effecten van de voorgenomen wijziging van het besluit emissie-eisen stookinstallaties B. http://www.ecn.nl/docs/library/report/2008/e08020.pdf
Ecologic Institute, 2011. Final report for the assessment of the 6th environmental action programme. http://www.ecologic.eu/files/attachments/Projects/2010/ecologic_6eap_report.pdf
Ecorys, 2013A. Report on the consultation on options for revision of the EU
Thematic Strategy on Air Pollution and related policies. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP%20Consultation%20report. pdf
Ecorys, 2013B. Services to assess the reasons for non-compliance with the ozone target values set by Directive 2008/50 i. To be published.
EEA, 2010. Air pollution — SOER 2010 thematic assessment. http://www.eea.europa.eu/soer/europe/air-pollution
EEA, 2012A. Air Quality in Europe - 2012 Report. http://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/air-quality-in-europe-2012
EEA, 2012B. Evaluation of progress under the EU National Emission Ceilings
Directive - Technical report No 14/2012. http://www.eea.europa.eu/highlights/publications/evaluation-progress-nec-2012
EEA, 2012C. Air pollution by ozone across Europe during summer 2012. http://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/air-pollution-by-ozone-across-EU-2012
EEA, 2013A. European Union emission inventory report 1990–2011 under the
UNECE Convention on Long-range Transboundary Air Pollution (LRTAP). http://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/eu-emission-inventory-report-lrtap
372 EEA, 2013B. Air Implementation Pilot, Lessons learnt from the implementation of air quality legislation at urban level. http://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/air-implementation-pilot-2013
EEA,2013C. NEC Directive status report 2012. http://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/nec-directive-status-report 2012/at_download/file
EGTEI, 2010. Options for limit values for emissions of dust from small combustion installations < 50 MWth. http://www.unece.org/fileadmin/DAM/env/documents/2010/eb/wg5/wg47/Inform al%20documents/Info.%20doc%209_Options%20for%20PM%20ELVs%20for%2 0SCI%20%20final.pdf
EMRC, 2013. Cost-benefit Analysis of Policy Scenarios for the Revision of the Thematic Strategy on Air Pollution. To be published.
Entec UK, 2005. National Emission Ceilings Directive Review Task 1: In-depth analysis of the NEC national programmes. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pollutants/pdf/final_report.pdf
Entec, 2009. Study to inform on-going discussions on the proposal for a Directive on industrial emissions. Part 1: Combustion Activities. Final Report to the European Commission.
Environment Agency Austria, 2012. Review of the Air Quality Directive and the 4th Daughter Directive, Service request no 6 under FW contract ENV.C.3/FRA/2009.0008. Final report 2012. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/SC6_final_report_v121210[1].pdf
EURELECTRIC, 2012. Power Statistics & Trends 2012 - synopsis. http://www.eurelectric.org/media/69408/synopsis_2012_hr-2012-180-0001-01- e.pdf
Eurobarometer, 2013. Attitudes of Europeans towards air quality. http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/flash_arch_360_345_en.htm#360
Europia, 2011. Annual Report. https://www.europia.eu/Content/Default.asp?PageID=412&DocID=35264
EUWEP, 2011. The EU Egg Industry - Welfare of Laying Hens, Presentation to Multi-Stakeholders Meeting on Implementation of Council Directive 1999/74/EC i (Brussels,
19 January 2011). http://ec.europa.eu/food/animal/welfare/farm/docs/19012011_4%20Industry%27s %20perspective%20-%20Williams.pdf
373 Finland’s environmental administration, 2003. (Summary of) Best Available Techniques in Small 5-50 MW Combustion Plants in Finland. provided by personal communication with Competent Authority, 22.12.2008. http://www.environment.fi/default.asp?contentid=23847&lan=fi
HTAP, 2010. Executive Summary of the LRTAP Task Force on Hemispheric Transport of Air Pollution (HTAP). http://www.htap.org/
IIASA, 2012A. The potential for further controls of emissions from mobile sources in Europe. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP-TRANSPORT-v2- 20121128.pdf
IIASA, 2012B. TSAP-2012 Baseline: Health and Environmental Impacts. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/tsap_impacts.pdf
IIASA, 2012C. Factors determining recent changes of emissions of air pollutants in Europe. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP-DISTANCE- 20120612[1].pdf
IIASA, 2012D. Future emissions of air pollutants in Europe – Current legislation baseline and the scope for further reductions. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP-BASELINE- 20120613[1].pdf
IIASA, 2012E. Emissions from households and other small combustion sources and their reduction potential. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP-SMALL_SOURCES- 20120612[1].pdf
IIASA, 2012F. Emissions from agriculture and their control potentials. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP-AGRI-20121129_v21.pdf
IIASA, 2013A. Policy Scenarios for the Revision of the Thematic Strategy on Air Pollution. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP-Report-10.pdf
IIASA, 2013B. Modelling compliance with NO2 and PM10 air quality limit values in the GAINS model. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TSAP-Report-.pdf
JRC, 2007. Small combustion installations: Techniques, emissions and measures for emission reduction. European Commission - Joint Research Centre. http://publications.jrc.ec.europa.eu/repository/handle/111111111/229
374 JRC, 2010. Evaluation of the livestock sector's contribution to the EU greenhouse gas emissions (GGELS), Final report. http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/analysis/external/livestock-gas/full_text_en.pdf
JRC-IPTS, 2013. Market based instruments to reduce air emissions from household heating appliances: Analysis of scrappage policy scenarios. To be published.
LEI Wageningen UR, 2009, Competitiveness of the EU dairy industry. http://www.lei.dlo.nl/publicaties/PDF/2009/2009-011.pdf
Norwegian Meteorological Institute, 2012A. Transboundary Acidification, Eutrophication and Ground Level Ozone in Europe in 2010. http://emep.int/publ/reports/2012/status_report_1_2012.pdf
Norwegian Meteorological Institute, 2012B.Transboundary air pollution by main pollutants (S, N, O3) and PM in 2010 - Belgium. http://www.emep.int/publ/reports/2012/Country_Reports/report_BE.pdf
Sutton, M. A. et al., 2011. The European Nitrogen Assessment: Sources, Effects and Policy Perspectives. Cambridge University Press.
TFEIP, 2012. Black carbon inventory study. http://tfeip-secretariat.org/2012-tfeip-meeting-bern/
TNO, 2012A. Survey of view of stakeholders, experts and citizens on the review of EU Air Policy. Part II: Detailed results. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/Survey%20AQD%20review%20- %20Part%20II%20Detailed%20results.pdf
TNO, 2012B. Final report of the PM Workshop Brussels 18-19 June 2012. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/TNOreport_FinalMinutesPMWork shop.pdf
Uk Government, 1993. Clean Air Act 1993. http://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/1993/11/contents
UNECE, 2011. Air Pollution Studies No20: Policy-relevant science questions. http://www.unece.org/index.php?id=25373
UNEP, 2008. Atmospheric Brown Cloud Regional Assessment. www.unep.org/pdf/ABCSummaryFinal.pdf
UNEP, 2011. Near-term climate protection and clean air benefits: actions for controlling short lived climate forcers. http://www.unep.org/publications/ebooks/slcf/
375 VITO, 2011. Beste Beschikbare Technieken (BBT) voor nieuwe, kleine en middelgrote stookinstallaties, stationaire motoren en gasturbines gestookt met fossiele brandstoffen. http://www.emis.vito.be/bbt-studie-stookinstallaties-en-stationaire-motorennieuwe-kleine-en-middelgrote
VITO, 2013. Specific evaluation of emissions from shipping including assessment for the establishment of possible new emission control areas in European Seas. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/air/pdf/review/Main%20Report%20Shipping.pdf
WHO, 2013A. REVIHAAP and HRAPIE projects. http://www.euro.who.int/en/what-we-do/health-topics/environment-and-health/airquality/activities/health-aspects-of-air-pollution-and-review-of-eu-policies-the- revihaap-and-hrapie-projects
WHO, 2013B. Review of Evidence on Health Aspects of Air Pollution - REVIHAAP Project. http://www.euro.who.int/__data/assets/pdf_file/0004/193108/REVIHAAP-Finaltechnical-report.pdf
376
23 dec '13 |
Voorstel voor een richtlijn van het Europees Parlement en de Raad ter vermindering van de nationale emissies van bepaalde luchtverontreinigende stoffen en tot wijziging van Richtlijn 2003/35/EG PROPOSAL |
Secretary-General of the European Commission 18167/13 |