COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposals for a Council Directive on a Common Corporate Tax Base and a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB)

1.

Kerngegevens

Document­datum 26-10-2016
Publicatie­datum 28-10-2016
Kenmerk 13730/16 ADD 2
Van Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director
Externe link origineel bericht
Originele document in PDF

2.

Tekst

Council of the European Union

Brussels, 26 October 2016 (OR. en)

13730/16

Interinstitutional File: ADD 2

2016/0337 (CNS) i

FISC 170 IA 99

PROPOSAL

From: Secretary-General of the European Commission, signed by Mr Jordi AYET PUIGARNAU, Director

date of receipt: 26 October 2016

To: Mr Jeppe TRANHOLM-MIKKELSEN, Secretary-General of the Council of the European Union

No. Cion doc.: SWD(2016) 341 final

Subject: COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT IMPACT ASSESSMENT Accompanying the document Proposals for a Council Directive on a

Common Corporate Tax Base and a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax

Base (CCCTB)

Delegations will find attached document SWD(2016) 341 final.

Encl.: SWD(2016) 341 final

EUROPEAN COMMISSION

Strasbourg, 25.10.2016 SWD(2016) 341 final

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT

IMPACT ASSESSMENT

Accompanying the document

Proposals for a Council Directive

on a Common Corporate Tax Base and a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB)

{COM(2016) 683 final i} {SWD(2016) 342 final} T ABLE OF C ONTENTS

  • 1. 
    INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................................... 4
  • 2. 
    THE PROBLEM AND WHY THE EUROPEAN UNION SHOULD ACT .............. 8

2.1. Problems with corporate taxation in an international context ........................... 8

2.2. Corporate taxation and its impact on financing and investment decisions .......................................................................................................... 12

2.3. How the problems affect stakeholders ............................................................ 19

2.4. Baseline scenario based on recent developments ............................................ 19

2.5. Subsidiarity and proportionality, EU added value .......................................... 21

  • 3. 
    OBJECTIVES ........................................................................................................... 22

3.1. General objective: Enhancing the fairness of the tax system .......................... 23

3.2. General objective: Stimulating growth and investment .................................. 23

  • 4. 
    POLICY OPTIONS ................................................................................................... 24

4.1. Option 1: No further EU action ....................................................................... 25

4.2. Option 2: CCCTB with a scope definition ...................................................... 26

4.3. Option 3: Solutions to address the debt bias ................................................... 27

4.4. Option 4: Options to incentivise R&D ............................................................ 28

4.5. Option 5: Staged approach .............................................................................. 30

  • 5. 
    ANALYSIS OF IMPACTS OF THE OPTIONS ...................................................... 31

5.1. Baseline vs CCCTB ......................................................................................... 33

5.2. Scope of the common consolidated base ......................................................... 40

5.3. Addressing the debt bias .................................................................................. 48

5.4. Treatment of R&D expenses ........................................................................... 56

5.5. The staged approach ........................................................................................ 63

5.6. Impact on SMEs .............................................................................................. 66

5.7. Social and environmental impacts ................................................................... 66

5.8. Conclusion on the preferred option ................................................................. 67

5.9. Choice of the corresponding policy instrument ............................................... 69

  • 6. 
    MONITORING AND EVALUATION ..................................................................... 69

6.1. Monitoring arrangements ................................................................................ 69

6.2. Evaluation ........................................................................................................ 71

  • 7. 
    GLOSSARY .............................................................................................................. 72
  • 8. 
    REFERENCES .......................................................................................................... 76 9. ANNEXES ................................................................................................................ 86

Annex I: Procedural Information .............................................................................. 87

Annex II: Stakeholder Consultation – Synopsis Report ............................................ 89

Annex III: Who is affected by the initiative and how ............................................. 107

Annex IV: Analytical Models used in preparing the Impact Assessment ............... 109

Annex V: Formula apportionment .......................................................................... 119

Annex VI: The Anti-Tax Avoidance Package ........................................................ 127

Annex VII: Compliance Costs ................................................................................ 130

Annex VIII: The 2011 Proposal for a CCCTB ........................................................ 139

Annex IX: Impact of the CCCTB on intra-group profit shifting ............................ 144

Annex X: Measuring the cost of capital and effective average tax rates ................ 145

Annex XI: Existence and design of R&D tax incentives in the EU ........................ 147

Annex XII: The impact on tax revenues ................................................................. 149

Annex XIII: Sensitivity analysis on the AGI and the ACE ..................................... 155 1. I NTRODUCTION

The taxation of multinational companies has come under scrutiny by tax administrations, tax experts and the general public in recent years. More and more evidence suggests that considerable amounts of corporate income generated in cross-border activities find ways to avoid taxation. The business models of multinational companies have become more complex, intra-group transactions have multiplied and multinationals' integrated value chains make it difficult to determine where profits are created. Governments struggle to determine within the current set of international tax rules which country should tax a multinational's income. Smaller businesses are put at a competitive disadvantage and citizens perceive tax systems as unfair since some corporate taxpayers might be able to avoid taxation by exploiting tax planning strategies. This perceived lack of fairness threatens the social contract between governments and their citizens and may impact overall tax compliance. More generally, the international tax rules suffer from inefficiencies and are non-transparent. On the other hand, companies still face a very complex patchwork of 28 national systems with high compliance costs and risks of double taxation.

The Commission announced in June 2015 to re-launch the proposal for a common

consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) to address these issues. 1 This report presents

the main findings from the impact assessment for this re-launch. The CCCTB was previously proposed by the European Commission in 2011, based on an impact assessment concluding that it would greatly improve the business environment in the single market, making it simpler and cheaper for companies to operate cross-border. Since 2011, new issues have come into light that reinforce the need for a common approach to corporate taxation in Europe.

First, aggressive tax planning strategies of multinational corporate groups have become more prevalent. As outlined above, these tax avoidance activities undermine the very principle of a deeper and fair single market and generate frustration among honest taxpayers who in recent years had to make additional efforts to consolidate public finances after the economic and financial crisis.

Second, the financial crisis has shed light on tax-induced corporate financing structures that weaken the resilience of businesses and put at risk the financial system and more generally the economy. Ideally, an efficient corporate tax system should be neutral with regard to the financing and investment decisions of companies.

Third, European growth and investment remain subdued and businesses in the EU are not investing enough in R&D activities in comparison to other major economies. European businesses need to remain competitive and innovative in a globalised world. The corporate tax system can play an important role in ensuring effective taxation while minimizing negative impacts on investment and growth.

The introduction of a CCCTB is central to those issues, as it aims to fundamentally reform corporate taxation and provide a European solution to the current challenges in

1 The Commission laid the groundwork for action on aggressive tax planning with its June 2015 action plan for a fair and efficient corporate tax system in the EU (COM/2015/302).

the international tax policy arena. It has been recognised that the CCCTB can serve as a powerful tool in the fight against corporate tax avoidance by removing exploitable differences and mismatches between national systems. To safeguard the CCCTB against profit shifting to third countries, it also needs to be equipped with common antiavoidance provisions, as spelled out in the June 2015 action plan. A single set of corporate tax rules will not only remove tax obstacles in the single market, but will make Europe more attractive to domestic and foreign investment. By making EU tax law simpler and reducing regulatory costs, it is expected to contribute to a clear, stable and predictable regulatory framework and improve tax certainty. At the same time, it provides for the opportunity to address existing financing and investment distortions and ensure sufficient R&D incentives. The CCCTB would hence contribute to the Commission's top priority of creating jobs, growth and investment.

Accordingly, the June 2015 action plan identified the CCCTB as a potentially effective tool to make corporate taxation fairer and more efficient. The action plan announced the re-launch of the CCCTB, while clarifying that it needed to be strengthened to address the current challenges in taxation. In that respect, the action plan referred to the fact that the CCCTB should be made compulsory, at least for multinational corporations, and that R&D incentives and measures to address current distortions would be considered. Developing a staged approach to implementing the CCCTB was recommended, focusing first on the common corporate tax base (common base henceforth) and in a second stage on the consolidation. The action plan also recalled the detrimental impact on European competitiveness of the current heavy compliance costs and administrative burdens created by the patchwork of 28 different national tax bases.

The re-launch of the CCCTB has been included in the 2016 Commission Work

Programme under the priority of creating a deeper and fairer single market. 2 The work

programme has also announced the withdrawal of the 2011 proposal. The 2016 re-launch builds on the 2011 proposal and adds the new elements as described above.

The analysis conducted in 2011 showed that the CCCTB has the potential to bring simplification and reduce costs for companies. It therefore contributes to the Commission's regulatory fitness and performance programme (REFIT). The CCCTB initiative has also been identified as one of the important milestones for building a capital

markets union (CMU). 3 In this context, the Commission committed to address the issue

of the debt-equity bias as part of the re-launch of the CCCTB. The preferential tax treatment of debt represents an obstacle for creating a stronger equity base in European companies.

The CCCTB is a major reform proposal to address the current challenges in corporate income taxation, but experience so far has shown that its negotiation in Council will need time. To address the most pressing issues in fighting aggressive tax planning the Commission committed in the June 2015 action plan to other actions aimed at ensuring in the shorter term effective taxation where profits are generated, a better tax environment for business, greater tax transparency and strong EU tools for coordination. As a result, the Anti-Tax Avoidance Package followed in January 2016. It includes legally-binding

2 COM(2015) 215 final i.

3 As described in the action plan on building a capital markets union, COM(2015)468final i, 30 September 2015.

anti-avoidance measures necessary to reduce aggressive tax planning. Tax transparency has been boosted by the Commission's proposals on tax rulings and on country-bycountry

reporting. 4 The Anti-Tax Avoidance Package complements existing initiatives

and forums to ensure effective taxation and transparency, such as the Code of Conduct or the Joint Transfer Pricing Forum. Compared to the more short-term measures, the relaunched CCCTB offers a holistic solution, which allows tackling important root causes of the tax avoidance problems.

The CCCTB defines the rules for calculating the taxable profits of a company. The tax base definition would be the same in all Member States under a CCCTB. However, the CCCTB does not seek to harmonize the national corporate tax rates. The level of taxation as determined by the statutory tax corporate rate remains a national decision. The CCCTB does not change either the domestic corporate tax systems for companies that are not captured by the scope of the directive or have not opted in. Also, the CCCTB does not replace bilateral tax treaties and transfer pricing rules which are still needed vis-à-vis third countries.

This impact assessment and the new CCCTB proposal build on the extensive work done by the CCCTB working group, the 2011 impact assessment and the technical work done

in collaboration with Member States following the 2011 proposal. 5 The impact

assessment presented in this document should thus be seen as part of a wider package of

technical studies on the subject 6 , complementing the existing material with further

evidence, with a focus specifically on the new elements and objectives. Due to the CCCTB's potential to considerably simplify the corporate income tax system in the EU,

this document was prepared as a regulatory fitness project of the European Commission. 7

The impact assessment is based on the following logic: The analysis starts with the withdrawal of the 2011 proposal. The absence of a CCCTB proposal coupled with the introduction of recent anti-tax avoidance initiatives is the baseline scenario. The impact of introducing a CCCTB as envisaged in 2011 is assessed and the analysis is further developed by studying the impact of possible new proposed elements to the CCCTB: a compulsory requirement for some companies, a solution for the debt bias, a tax incentive for R&D and a staged approach for its introduction to facilitate the political process.

The analysis concludes that the preferred option would be a CCCTB that is mandatory for very large multinational companies and optional for others, that includes an allowance for growth and investment (AGI) with well-designed anti-avoidance measures and that contains an additional allowance for R&D expenses.

4 COM(2016) 198 final i.

5 The analysis the 2011 proposal and impact assessment was based on many years of work and input

from within the Commission, external contractors and Member States (CCCTB Working Group) as well as other stakeholders. The CCCTB Working Group produced 68 papers and summary records of their meetings between 2004 and 2010. All material is published on a dedicated DG TAXUD website: http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/taxation/company_tax/common_tax_base/index_en.htm . 6 Annex VIII gives an overview of the 2011 proposal, the underlying impact assessment and the

subsequent technical work.

6

Box 1: The 2011 proposal for a CCCTB

The Commission has highlighted the issues and challenges of corporate tax systems in an Economic Union as well as their role for competitiveness vis-à-vis third countries for many decades. In 2001, the Commission presented a communication identifying concrete steps to eliminate tax obstacles to crossborder trade in the EU. This was followed by 10 years of technical preparation, culminating in the Commission's 2011 proposal for a CCCTB.

The Commission tabled in March 2011 a proposal for a directive on a CCCTB which lays down common rules for the calculation of the tax base applicable to companies operating in the EU. This EU tax framework comprises a full set of corporate tax rules to calculate the individual fiscal results of companies and permanent establishments which are tax resident, or situated, in the EU. The system includes rules for consolidating those results (profits and losses) when there are other group members and to apportion the consolidated tax base to all relevant Member States if it is positive. In other words, a qualifying company or group of companies would have to comply with only one set of rules for computing its taxable income, rather than different rules in each Member State where it operates. The consolidated tax base would be apportioned on the basis of a fixed formula comprising three equally weighted factors: sales (by destination), labour and assets. Each Member State would apply its own tax rate to the share of the tax base apportioned through the formula. Only the calculation and apportionment of the tax base would be harmonised. Member States would retain the power to set their own tax rates.

The CCCTB was proposed as an optional system. All companies, irrespective of size or whether they had cross-border operations, would be entitled, but not obliged, to apply the system, provided that they fulfilled the eligibility requirements of the Directive. The proposal also includes anti-abuse rules and stipulates how Member States should administer the CCCTB under a 'one-stop-shop' approach.

In 2011, the CCCTB was primarily envisaged as a tool for removing tax obstacles which companies occasionally suffer when they operate cross-border within the internal market. Companies would thus benefit from cross-border loss relief, which is an automatic outcome of consolidation (i.e. no more paying tax on profits in one Member State to the extent that unrelieved losses are being made at the same time in another Member State). The apportionment of the tax base through a formula would remove the requirement for lengthy and costly recording and negotiating of intra-group transactions at notional arm's length prices (i.e. no more transfer pricing within a CCCTB group). Accordingly, compliance costs would be reduced by providing for a single set of tax rules for calculating the tax base. Having a common set of rules would also reduce the possibility of double taxation or double nontaxation and mismatches in general.

Intensive technical discussions followed in Council. After a first reading was completed, the High Level Working Party (HLWP) agreed in March 2013 that work on the proposal should be structured as a step-by-step approach and Member States should prioritise the matters related to the tax base. Accordingly, consolidation would have to be addressed in a second step once the work on the base would have been sufficiently advanced. At the time, Member States also stated that the proposal was not yet ready for a political discussion.

After technical work on the elements of the tax base was accomplished, attention shifted towards highlighting the link between the CCCTB and the OECD initiative against Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS). In this framework, discussions focussed on the international aspects of the tax base as well as certain elements of the CCCTB system, such as controlled foreign company (CFC) legislation and the interest limitation rule. Both are closely linked to the OECD BEPS work.

At the informal ECOFIN of October 2014, the Council discussed how to make concrete progress on the CCCTB in the short to medium term. It was concluded that future work should primarily be centred on the international aspects of the system.

On 28 th January 2016 and while work on the re-launched CCCTB proposal was progressing, the Commission tabled a proposal for a directive against tax avoidance practices. As a matter of fact, the proposed instrument included most of the elements of the international and BEPS related aspects of the

CCCTB in an effort to lay down a coordinated approach to implementing certain common minimum standards against tax avoidance in the EU.

  • 2. 
    T HE PROBLEM AND WHY THE E UROPEAN U NION SHOULD ACT

    2.1. Problems with corporate taxation in an international context

Drivers

The taxation of multinational companies has increasingly come under scrutiny in recent years. The business models of multinational companies have become more complex and increasing evidence suggests that considerable amounts of corporate income can avoid taxation.

The root of the problem stems from current international practices for the distribution of taxable profits in combination with the increase in capital mobility over the last decades. Capital mobility within the EU has been fostered by the increased economic integration following key achievements towards a single market and the implementation of a common currency in the euro area. While this has helped businesses in their cross-border activities and increased welfare of citizens, the increased capital mobility conflicts with the lack of coordination of tax policies at the international level. Not only do tax obstacles still exist in the single market, but tax authorities also struggle to determine which country should own the rights to tax which share of a multinational's income.

Figure 1: Problem tree

Source: European Commission

The interplay between these factors creates incentives for governments to compete for highly mobile tax bases, notably accounting profits as well as income related to intangible assets. In fact, the economic literature shows that governments have reacted to increased mobility by reducing the statutory corporate tax rates while broadening the tax bases to lower the risk of profits being shifted outside the country. Governments have also implemented specific regimes to attract highly mobile tax bases such as royalty and license payments. This form of tax competition increasingly replaces tax competition based on headline statutory tax rates and opens up new non-transparent tax planning

opportunities. 8 Recent evidence points to tax competition being particularly strong within

the EU due to the high economic integration and low trade costs within the EU (Streif,

2015). 9 The continued strengthening of the single market with respect to goods, capital

and labour in the absence of tax harmonisation has intensified this effect (Redoano, 2014).

While incentives for tax competition have increased, there is at the same time a tendency to protect domestic tax bases through anti-avoidance rules. Introducing anti-abuse measures by Member States is a valuable short-term solution to fix the most pressing issues. However, the uncoordinated implementation of such measures can create new barriers to cross-border investments and thereby hamper the overarching goals of the single market, the creation of a capital markets union and the overall attractiveness of the EU at the global level. Moreover, they render the international corporate income tax (CIT) system ever more complex, which in itself may exacerbate the tax avoidance problem. More generally, uncoordinated national actions contribute to creating new tax mismatches and loopholes that can be exploited by multinational firms.

Problems

Improvements in the tax area to the functioning of the single market have brought some key advantages to multinational companies active in several EU countries. Notably, they benefit from withholding tax exemptions on intra-group interest, royalty and dividend

payments and from tax-neutral cross-border reorganisations 10 , as well as a fairly narrow

application of controlled foreign company (CFC) rules between most EU Member

States. 11 In short, they are treated as if they were operating only domestically. At the

same time, their multinational group structure allows them to exploit mismatches in the interaction of national tax systems, locate intellectual property where they achieve the most attractive tax savings and treaty-shop in the EU for the most attractive withholding tax regimes vis-à-vis a specific third country.

The existence of tax avoidance in the form of profit shifting and base eroding practices is demonstrated in many academic studies. Although the extent of these practices and their impact on total tax revenues is hard to measure, the existing evidence suggests it is considerable. The OECD/G20 BEPS report on Action 11 for example estimates the revenue loss at the global level at 4-10% of CIT revenue, i.e. USD 100-240 billion

8 Evidence for tax competition and the evolution of tax rates and bases in the EU have been summarised in the Staff Working Document accompanying the June 2015 action plan (European Commission, 2015b).

9 Low trade costs have two effects: (1) they tend to concentrate foreign direct investment from third

countries in one Member State, from where other Member States are reached via exports instead of investing more evenly in the EU; (2) with decreasing trade costs, foreign direct investment within the EU might become relatively less attractive compared to intra-EU exports.

10 According to the rules laid down in the Merger Directive, the Parent-Subsidiary Directive and the

Interest and Royalty Directive. 11 Following the European Court of Justice Decision, the fundamental freedoms imply that CFC rules in

the EU only apply to wholly artificial arrangements. The situation is slightly different in Denmark (where CFC rules also apply to domestic cases), Lithuania (which applies a white list for EU countries, but subject to conditions) and the UK (which has not implemented a specific clause for the EU) (see page 58 of ZEW (2016c) for a discussion).

annually at 2014 levels. In a study covering 51 countries, the IMF concludes that "the (unweighted) average revenue loss is about 5 per cent of current CIT revenue – but almost 13 per cent in non-OECD countries". Additionally, a recent study commissioned by the European Parliamentary Research Service finds that the revenue loss from profit shifting amounts to about EUR 50-70 billion in the EU, equivalent to 17-23% of CIT revenue in 2013.

Other studies have not attempted to measure the total revenue loss, but are nonetheless indicative of the potential size of the problem. Lee et al. (2015) find that 22% of companies in their sample have a 'large tax gap', meaning that their tax payments correspond to at most 90% of the taxes they would theoretically owe according to where they generate their revenues. Furthermore, there is evidence of the sensitivity of affiliates' profits to CIT rates: reported profits are higher in low-tax jurisdictions than in high-tax

jurisdictions. 12 Synthesizing 25 studies, Heckemeyer and Overesch (2013) find that an

increase in the CIT rate by 1 percentage point leads to a lowering of affiliates' pre-tax profits by 0.8% on average.

An important cross-border tax obstacle for companies active in several Member States is having to deal with up to 28 different rulebooks and up to 28 different tax administrations. They also have to deal with international rules set by bilateral tax treaties between Member States. In addition, they are faced with an extremely complex system for determining how intra-group transactions should be taxed (transfer pricing),

and often cannot offset their losses in one Member State against profits in another. 13 The

result is that most businesses are faced with high costs and complexities, while smaller businesses are often completely deterred from expanding within the EU. This could be particularly detrimental for young companies that foster innovation dynamics and are an engine of job creation. Cross-border obstacles hindering the functioning of the single

market motivated the 2011 proposal for a CCCTB 14 and most of the 2011 findings on

these obstacles are still valid today. A majority of companies find the current regimes difficult to operate, particularly transfer pricing requirements and dealing with audits in

various Member States. 15 The latest available statistics under the EU arbitration

convention show that the number of pending disputes has further increased since 2008

and the number of requests to resolve disputes has also gone up in recent years. 16

Moreover, the growing number of anti-avoidance regulations adds to the complexity of the international corporate tax system, potentially creating additional double taxation cases and leading to higher administrative costs for both businesses and administrations.

Consequences

The negative consequences resulting from corporate tax avoidance, the complex international tax system and other tax obstacles are manifold, but they particularly raise

12 See Sullivan (2004) and Clausing (2011).

13 Denmark is one exemption, where corporations can opt for international joint taxation for the group.

14 Corporate taxation has been recognised much earlier as a fundamental component of the single market.

See e.g. the 2000 report by the CEPS Tax Task Force, Radaelli (2000) and the discussion in annex X. 15 These findings are based on a 2013 review of methods to compute compliance costs (Ramboll

Management Consulting, The Evaluation Partnership and Europe Economic Research, 2013).

16 The EU arbitration convention establishes a procedure to resolve disputes where double taxation

occurs between enterprises of different Member States as a result of an upward adjustment of taxable profits by one Member State.

issues of fairness among taxpayers and may constitute barriers to cross-border investment. Tax avoidance leads to a poor congruence between the jurisdiction where the value is created and the one where corporate profits are taxed. This contributes to an unfair distribution of the tax burden, alongside a tendency of national governments to respond by tapping less mobile tax bases, an additional benefit for multinational businesses. In the light of fiscal adjustment needs following the economic and financial crisis (public debt levels have increased in the EU from around 58% of GDP in 2007 to an estimated 86% of GDP in 2017), many governments have cut expenditures and increased taxes, notably on consumption, to consolidate public budgets. This has raised a question about multinationals and their fair contribution to government budgets.

There is clear evidence for an uneven playing field between multinational entities and domestic firms. A recent study by the ZEW (2016c) has shown that the use of crossborder tax planning in the EU can considerably reduce effective taxation levels (Table

1). 17 Tax planning reduces both the mean effective average tax rate (EATR) in the EU as well as the minimum and maximum EATRs 18 . The average reduction is substantial.

Lower effective taxation levels for multinational entities have also been evidenced empirically. For instance, Egger et al. (2010) compare the tax liabilities of multinationals with those of domestic firms and find that foreign-owned affiliates in high-tax European countries pay 32% less tax than domestically owned companies. A similar study by Finke (2013) for Germany finds a gap of 27%.

Table 1: Impact of tax planning on effective average tax rates

% Mean Min Max Average EU-28 percentage reduction

Effective average tax rate domestic case 21.1 9.0 38.3 n/a

Effective average tax rate after crossborder tax planning via

Hybrid financing 13.7 4.3 26.6 -36.3%

Intellectual property box (patent box) -1.6 -3.7 1.8 -108.3%

Financing via offshore treaty 15.9 6.4 28.6 -25.0%

Source: ZEW (2015, 2016c) and own computations

Notes: Hybrid financing: A parent located in the EU or the US finances an intermediate company located in an 'EU average' country which grants a 'hybrid loan' to a subsidiary located in the EU. The hybrid loan is treated as equity in the EU average country and as a loan in the subsidiary country.

Intellectual property box: A parent located in the EU finances both, an intermediate company in an EU country that has an attractive intellectual property box regime and another subsidiary in the EU or the US. The intermediate company licenses the intellectual property to the subsidiary and receives royalties from the subsidiary. The figures show the extreme case where the intellectual property is the only productive asset of the multinational. . Financing via offshore treaty: A parent located in the EU or the US finances an intermediate company located in a zero-tax country which has concluded tax treaties with EU countries. The intermediate company grants a loan to a subsidiary located in the EU and receives interest payments from the subsidiary. Mean: In the domestic case the mean is the simple EU-28 average, while in cross-border cases, the mean is the average over all possible combinations of parent-subsidiary locations in the EU-28 and the US.

17 The possibilities for hybrid loan financing by corporate groups and the ensuing double-non taxation have been reduced due to the 2014 amendment of the Parent-Subsidiary Directive, effective as of 2016.

18 Effective average tax rates are driven by the respective statutory CIT rate in each country, which partly explains the wide spread.

Aside from the harmful perception of the tax system being unfair, including its negative impact on taxpayer morale (see discussion in Section 5.1), the resulting competitive distortions weigh negatively on the economy. Tax avoidance and aggressive tax planning by multinational companies distort price signals in the single market and thereby the allocation of resources. A recent study by the OECD estimates that mark-ups of multinational entities are on average 10% higher than those of domestic groups with similar characteristics while the mark-up of a tax-planning MNE is up to 23% higher. For multinational groups with links to zero-tax countries or operating in a large number of countries the mark-ups are estimated to be even higher. Multinational enterprises are also

found to operate in more concentrated industries. 19 Companies which use tax avoidance

are more profitable and face lower capital costs compared to domestic companies. Higher

mark-ups weigh on growth and are detrimental to equality. 20 In addition, important

economic resources are wasted on unproductive tax planning activities.

On the other hand, the negative consequences highlighted in the 2011 impact assessment remain: high tax compliance costs and double taxation risks coupled with few possibilities for cross-border loss offset constitute an important barrier to cross-border investment and impede the EU's attractiveness as an investment destination.

The main findings on tax compliance costs for firms from the 2011 impact assessment were that they are high and significant, mostly due to frequent changes and complexity of tax laws, and that they are regressive: The estimate for large companies is about 2% of taxes paid, while for small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) the figure is about 30% of taxes paid. These findings are confirmed in a survey of empirical estimates by Eichfelder and Vaillancourt (2014) for the period between 1984 and 2014. Research also

shows that those compliance costs do not appear to be diminishing over time. 21

Evidence on cross-border tax compliance costs remains scarce, even though they are arguably higher than in the domestic case since the rules of two countries have two be applied in addition to international tax rules which have to be considered (double tax treaties). In line with this, the 2011 impact assessment finds that compliance costs increase with cross-border activity and with increasing number of subsidiaries. Early contributions such as the 1992 Ruding report provide a first survey of cross-border compliance costs for EU companies, which were found to be at around 3% of total

income of the surveyed companies. 22 A more detailed overview of the main findings on

tax compliance costs is provided in annex VII.

2.2. Corporate taxation and its impact on financing and investment decisions

Implementing a European corporate tax base offers the opportunity to create a more neutral and investment friendly tax system. This would contribute to a successful capital markets union, attract inward investment to the EU, and result in a more resilient

19 See OECD (2015d), p. 169.

20 See Ilzkovitz and Dierx (2016) for a discussion.

21 See Lignier and Evans (2012) and Lignier, Evans and Tran-Nam (2014).

22 The summary of compliance cost issues in annex 2 of the 2001 Communication on tax obstacles in the

internal market provides a summary of the results of the Ruding survey as well as a discussion of the literature available at the time.

corporate sector by removing financing distortions. 23 Taxation is indeed a key

component of the business environment. It influences companies' investment and innovation decisions through its impact on the cost of capital. Two issues stand out in particular: the debt bias and the tax treatment of R&D expenditures.

2.2.1. Debt bias

Drivers and problems

Most corporate tax systems favour debt over equity because interest expenses for debt are largely tax deductible in contrast to equity costs. The result is a difference in effective taxation between investments financed by debt and those financed by equity. The debt bias has been recognized by the European Commission and other relevant international

organisations as a major problem. 24

Figure 2: Cost of capital - difference between new equity and debt financing

Source: ZEW (2015, 2016a)

Note: The graph shows the cost of capital at the level of the company for new equity and debt as well as the difference between them for each Member State in 2015. The indicator takes into account the ACE provisions in Belgium and Italy. The assumption is that the notional interest rate granted is equal to the market interest rate in the model. This results in full financing neutrality.

Because of this different tax treatment, an equity financed investment needs to earn a pretax return that is higher than the one required by a debt financed investment. In a concrete example this means that if the investing company has an alternative safe investment that earns 5%, the investment financed by debt would need a pre-tax return of

23 This is in line with the tax recommendations in the European Semester.

24 See for example the various Annual Growth Surveys published by the European Commission in the context of the European Semester, the action plan on building a capital markets union, the publications of the International Monetary Fund (IMF, 2009, 2010; de Mooij, 2011a) or the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD, 2015a), and the Financial Stability Board (2015).

only 4%, while equity needs to earn 6.1%. 25 Figure 2 presents this 'required return' - also

called cost of capital - for Member States in 2015. It shows that the bias is present in nearly all countries, as the cost of capital for investment financed by new equity is larger than the cost of capital for investment financed by debt.

Consequences

There is ample empirical evidence that the corporate debt bias significantly affects financing decisions of companies, both in the financial and the non-financial corporate sector. In the non-financial sector, de Mooij (2011b) finds that a 10 percentage point higher corporate tax rate increases the debt-asset ratio by between 1.7 and 2.8 percentage

points. 26 The result is an increased indebtedness of non-financial companies due to the debt bias. 27

The debt bias encourages non-financial corporations to use more debt than equity. The higher leverage makes companies more fragile and less resilient and may result in an increased volatility of the business cycle and disproportionate levels of bankruptcy costs. Indeed, Sørensen (2015) estimates that the debt bias leads to a debt-asset ratio which is

about 2-3 percentage points above the socially optimal level 28 . This is partly attributed to

the fact that firms do not account for the welfare costs of financial distress when choosing their debt levels.

The debt bias also has a negative impact on growth. According to research conducted at the Bank for International Settlements, debt levels exceeding 90% of GDP for the nonfinancial

corporate sector become deleterious for growth. 29 This negative effect of debt

on growth is also identified by the European Central Bank (2014, p. 112). In 2014 the non-consolidated non-financial corporate debt level in percent of GDP was above that

level in 18 of the 28 Member States and was above 150% in six of them. 30

The debt bias misallocates capital and may hamper the growth of stock market capitalization, the latter being associated with higher GDP per capita. In addition, the debt bias is particularly detrimental for young and innovative firms, whose access to external funding is more difficult. Thus it puts at a disadvantage exactly those firms that are important for economic growth (including by slowing down the exit of highlyindebted low-productivity firms). As a consequence the welfare costs associated with the

25 Annex X explains the underlying model.

26 This result could be a lower bound: recent studies that rely on tax return data rather than commercial

balance sheets find that the estimated tax effect on capital structure using financial statements is likely to be biased downward. Devereux et al. (2015) show that the external leverage of domestic stand-alone companies and of multinational companies responds strongly to corporate tax incentives.

27 Taxation is not the only driver of indebtedness but econometric techniques allow disentangling the

respective effects of the various drivers and point to a large role for taxation. 28 The socially optimal level is defined as the one that maximises total rent to society generated by an

investment. See also equation 3.1 in Sørensen (2015). 29 See Cecchetti et al. (2011).

30 Source: Eurostat. Latest available data. The instruments that are taken into account to compile debt of

non-financial corporations are Debt securities (F.3) and Loans (F.4). Data are presented in nonconsolidated terms, i.e. including transactions within the same sector.

lack of deductibility of the cost of equity for young and innovative firms may be

particularly relevant. Overall, the welfare impact is not negligible. 31

Recent research has also shown that despite stricter capital requirements for banks, the debt bias also plays a significant role in the financing structure of financial institutions, in clear opposition with the aims of regulations strengthening the equity base. For banks with an amount of equity larger than the minimum regulatory requirement, the responsiveness of the debt-asset ratio to corporate tax rate increases is similar to the one

for the non-financial sector. 32 Moreover, the adverse impacts in the non-financial and

financial sectors reinforce each other to the extent that the sectors provide funds to each other. By discouraging firms from building a strong equity base and tapping capital markets, the debt bias has contributed to excessive leverage also in the financial sector and potentially magnified the negative effects of the financial crisis: Langedijk et al. (2014) and de Mooij et al. (2014) find that eliminating the debt bias could decrease both the likelihood of financial crises and their costs for public finances. The potential gains from the reduced probability and cost of crises are estimated by both studies to be between 0.5 and 11-12% of GDP (reflecting the low and high range of tax elasticities).

Finally, the preferential tax treatment of debt generates opportunities for aggressive tax planning. At a cross-border level, the deductibility of interest expenses creates opportunities to decrease reported profit via debt-shifting – for example by using hybrid

instruments (considered as equity in one country, but as debt in another). 33 Figure 3

summarises the different drivers and consequences of the debt bias.

31 See Fatica et al. (2013, p. 11) for a discussion.

32 Empirical evidence for the debt bias in the financial sector is among others provided by Gropp and

Heider (2010), Hemmelgarn and Teichmann (2014) and Keen and de Mooij (2012). 33 Huizinga et al. (2008) provide empirical evidence for this type of profit shifting.

Figure 3: Problem tree – Debt Bias

Source: European Commission

2.2.2. The tax treatment of R&D expenditures

Drivers

R&D investment is a key driver of productivity and economic growth. However, private companies do not sufficiently invest in R&D from a welfare perspective. The reason is that companies do not take into account the positive externality from knowledge spillovers which benefit the whole economy. Indeed, the social returns from R&D investment are estimated to be two to three times higher than the private returns of firms

on the investment. 34 In addition, the risk and the uncertainty of returns are much higher

for R&D investments and their returns are highly skewed, which again leads to lower

investment. 35 The IMF (2016) shows that fully internalizing the externalities of R&D

would lead to 40% higher investments compared to the status quo. Such an increase could lift GDP in individual economies by 5% in the long term - and globally by as much as 8% due to international spillovers.

34 See Parsons and Phillips (2007), Sveikauskas (2007), Bloom, Schankerman, and van Reenen (2013).

35 See Scherer and Harhoff (2000).

Figure 4: Evolution of business R&D intensity, 2000-2014

3.5 %

3.0 % South Korea

(1)

Japan

2.5 %

2.0 % United States

(2)

China

(3)

1.5 %

EU

1.0 %

0.5 %

2000 2005 2010 2015

Source: DG Research and Innovation, based on Eurostat and OECD data. Business R&D spending in % of GDP

Notes: Business R&D intensity measured as business R&D expenditure in % of GDP.

(1) South Korea: break in the series between 2007 and the previous years. (2) USA: business enterprise expenditure on R&D (BERD) does not include most or all capital expenditure. (3) China: break in the series between 2009 and previous years.

Problems and Consequences

The underinvestment in business R&D is particularly pronounced in the EU. While the world is becoming more R&D-intensive, the relative weight of the EU is decreasing, mainly due to the rapid rise of China. The EU is moreover not on track to reach its target of investing 3% of GDP in (total private and public) R&D by 2020. The underinvestment in business R&D is one of the reasons behind the widening of the EU's productivity gap compared to the US. The shortfall mainly reflects a deficit in business R&D expenditure. Business in the EU spend far less on R&D than businesses, e.g. in the US and Japan, and the latest figures show a further increase of the gap (Figure 4). To reach the 3% R&D target, large additional R&D investments are needed. Assuming that two thirds of the investment should come from the private sector, the business R&D investment gap was EUR 98 billion in 2014.

Figure 5: R&D intensity and business R&D intensity projections for the EU

3.5

3.0 Target

(2)

2.5 Trend (1)

R&D intensity 2.0

Target

(3)

1.5 Business R&D

intensity Trend

(1)

1.0

0.5

2005 2010 2015 2020

Source: DG Research and Innovation, DG Eurostat

Notes: R&D intensity is measured as R&D expenditure in % of GDP.

(1) The projections based on trends are derived from compound annual growth in R&D intensity and business R&D intensity between 2007 and 2014. (2) R&D intensity: the projection is based on R&D intensity target of 3% for 2020. (3) Business R&D intensity: the projection is based on a business R&D intensity target of 2% for 2020.

R&D tax incentives are an important policy tool, which is now used by the majority of EU countries (and beyond). In response to the challenging economic environment, almost all Member States widened their R&D tax incentives and five other countries have

introduced new measures. 36 The OECD (2016) estimates that R&D tax support

accounted for at least 43% of fiscal support for business R&D in 2013. However, not all

measures are effective. 37 The diversity of schemes could result in an increasingly

complex landscape for R&D tax treatment in Europe hindering trans-European collaboration. In its 2006 Communication on the more effective use of tax incentives in favour of R&D, the Commission already encouraged Member States to improve the use and coordination of R&D tax incentives. Figure 6 summarises the different elements discussed above in a problem tree which relates drivers, problems and consequences.

36 See Garnier et al. (2014) for an overview of tax reforms in the EU.

37 Governments can draw on several experiences with the design of R&D tax incentives given that such schemes have been deployed in most advanced economies over the last decade or longer. These experiences are evaluated in a study by CPB (2014) carried out for the European Commission in 2014 which also benefited from exchanges with Member States representatives and concluded with a list of good practices in terms of the design of R&D tax incentives.

Figure 6: Problem tree – R&D

Source: European Commission

2.3. How the problems affect stakeholders

Multinational enterprises are negatively affected by the problems outlined above to the extent that they have to deal with numerous national tax systems which creates high compliance costs and uncertainty. On the other hand, some companies do benefit from the tax planning opportunities generated by the current international tax architecture.

SMEs face high costs of investing and growing abroad due to differences across national tax systems. There is no level-playing-field since SMEs cannot reduce their tax burdens by tax planning measures which leads to distortions in the internal market and raises fairness issues.

The current tax systems provide incentives for Member States to possibly engage in harmful tax competition to attract highly mobile tax bases. As a consequence of such tax competition, some Member States will lose tax bases, while others gain from adopting tax provisions that are advantageous for attracting mobile tax bases.

Citizens perceive the fairness of tax systems being hampered by the fact that some taxpayers have means to reduce their tax burden significantly by playing with the rules. This perception can reduce overall tax morale and more broadly damage the social contract between citizens and governments.

2.4. Baseline scenario based on recent developments

The baseline scenario assumes that the CCCTB as tabled in 2011 is withdrawn. It reflects the latest initiatives to clamp down on corporate tax avoidance and ensure fair and efficient taxation in the EU. The June 2015 action plan acknowledged that the CCCTB is a very ambitious proposal that would require time to be completed. It identified several actions aimed in the shorter term at enhancing effective taxation where profits are generated, creating a better tax environment for business, enhancing tax transparency and strengthening EU tools for coordination.

Following the crisis and the increased revenue needs, the OECD proposed an action plan on base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS) to reinforce the current international tax rules and stabilise national tax bases. The BEPS project focuses on the interaction of different (national) tax rules and tries to detect and close loopholes in the current tax architecture.

The action plan laid the basis for developing an EU approach 38 to implementing some

international aspects of the common base that are linked to the OECD/G20 BEPS project.

As a result, the Commission proposed in January 2016 the Anti-Tax Avoidance Package, made up of four proposals to ensure that tax is paid where the value is generated and that tax information is effectively accessed. The elements of the package are detailed in annex

VIII. Its central element is the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive 39 , which was politically

agreed by the Council on 21st June 2016 and legally adopted on 12th July 2016. It puts forward tax rules aimed at preventing that income goes untaxed (or taxed at very low level), inter alia an interest limitation rule, controlled foreign company rules, and rules on hybrid mismatches.

The other elements of the package consist of: (i) an Amendment to the existing Directive on administrative cooperation to implement automatic exchange of information on country-by-country reports of multinational companies with consolidated revenues of at least EUR 750 million; (ii) a Recommendation on Tax Treaty issues; (iii) a Communication on External Strategy for Effective Taxation setting out a coordinated EU approach against external risks of tax avoidance and to promote international tax good governance.

The Anti-Tax Avoidance Package complements existing initiatives and forums to ensure an effective taxation, enhance tax transparency and address the risk of double taxation. The proposal for an automatic exchange of information on tax rulings was adopted by the Council in December 2015. A proposal to introduce public reporting requirements for multinational entities with turnover above EUR 750 million was adopted by the Commission in April 2016. In line with the action plan of June 2015, the Commission is currently exploring various options for a coordinated EU approach to improve dispute resolution mechanisms, following a public consultation. The Commission is also willing to respond to the invitation for tabling a proposal on hybrid mismatches involving third countries, as this arises from the statement which accompanied the political agreement on the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive.

Thus the baseline scenario, against which all policy options will be evaluated, is one in which there is no CCCTB, but the Anti-Tax Avoidance Package and public country-bycountry reporting are implemented.

38 This would allow for a coordinated implementation of the new international standards agreed in the package. The Treaties require that the fundamental rights – including the freedom of establishment – be respected. Reforms must therefore be tailored for the EU content and fix inconsistencies on an EU- wide basis.

39 10426/16 FISC 104 ECOFIN 628

2.5. Subsidiarity and proportionality, EU added value

Subsidiarity

Although the problems and market distortions explained in the previous subsections have distinct origins, it seems that their harmful effects can be tackled effectively only through a common solution: that is, the approximation of corporate tax regimes in the EU would mitigate distortions in the market by creating a fairer and more coherent tax environment for businesses. For this objective to come into fruition, action is necessary to be taken not separately by Member States in an uncoordinated fashion, but at the level of the Union instead. Initiatives, planned and implemented by each Member State individually, would only perpetuate, or even exacerbate, the current situation, as taxpayers would still need to deal with 28 diverse and sometimes, conflicting tax systems.

The envisaged re-launch of the CCCTB aims to respond to the need for increased growth and job creation in the post-crisis EU, as well as countering aggressive tax planning practices. All these objectives essentially seek to tackle problems beyond a single Member State which by nature require a common approach. In this light, any measures could only bring results if the rules were applied in a uniform fashion across the single market. If not, the landscape in the field of corporate taxation would remain fragmented and the current situation would persist, allowing fiscal obstacles and unfair tax competition practices to continue to flourish.

What is more, tax avoidance practices are nowadays primarily set up in a cross-border context. It is indeed the interaction between different tax systems that generates opportunities for abuse or facilitates taking advantage of mismatches in the interaction of national corporate tax rules. In addition, the fact that the EU is an internal market with a high degree of integration presumes enhanced cross-border activity, which underscores the significance of agreeing to coordinated solutions.

More specifically, most key features of the CCCTB system, such as relief for crossborder losses, tax-free internal group restructurings, the elimination of complex intragroup transfer pricing as well as the apportionment of revenues by a formula at the level of a group have a cross-border underpinning and could only be addressed within a

context of common regulation. 40 Thus, the EU added value follows from the fact that a

certain degree of uniformity is necessary for the purpose of effectively tackling identified distortions in the market caused by mismatches, double taxation or non-taxation. Common rules are also a prerequisite for creating a 'one-stop-shop' for companies or groups of companies operating across the EU.

Considering the scale and effects of the envisaged CCCTB, its objectives would be better achieved at Union level, to attenuate the distortions resulting from the current interaction of 28 national tax regimes and create more favourable conditions for cross-border investment in the single market.

Proportionality

The envisaged measures are both suitable and necessary for achieving the desired end. They do not go further than harmonising the corporate tax base, which is a prerequisite

40 For an overview of the elements of the CCCTB mentioned here see also annex X.

for curbing identified obstacles that distort the single market. Furthermore, the explored initiatives do not restrict Member States' capability to determine the composition and desired amount of tax revenues that they collect in order to meet their budgetary policy targets. In this regard, they do not affect Member States' sovereignty over setting their own corporate tax rates.

Although the Commission has consistently promoted the coordination of national tax practices, coordination alone is not sufficient for eradicating tax-related distortions in the single market. Experience has shown that coordination is a slow process and the results of such exercises have hitherto been modest. Moreover, tax coordination typically addresses only specific, targeted issues and cannot cater for the wide variety of problems faced by companies in the single market.

The rules would contribute to improving the functioning of the single market through a more efficient way for collectively managing problems that emerge from the interaction of disparate national corporate tax systems.

EU added value

The taxation of multinational companies in a framework of national corporate tax systems and bilateral tax treaties faces considerable challenges. While the integration of markets has made progress and generates benefits for companies as well as for citizens, the taxation of income from corporate activities across the EU remains a national task. This can lead to frictions in the single market due to tax obstacles.

In this context, the value-added of EU action is to maintain and further improve capital mobility within the Union by decreasing compliance costs and tax obstacles. At the same time, EU action ensures that the activities of multinational companies within the EU do not avoid a fair level of taxation. An integrated EU approach to the taxation of corporate income allows Member States to tax the income generated within their boundaries with the corporate tax rate they consider appropriate. A common approach to an EU tax base therefore helps to re-establish the link between taxation and value creation. Acting at EU level would not only replace the current mechanism of taxing corporate profits with a system based on attributing income where the real economic activity takes place, it would also eliminate the costly transfer pricing procedures since the tax base would be consolidated at EU level.

  • 3. 
    O BJECTIVES

The June action plan announced the CCCTB as a proposal to strengthen the single market by ensuring a fair, efficient and growth-friendly corporate tax system which is immune to aggressive tax planning practices and based on the principle that companies should pay taxes in the country where profits are generated. Work on this impact assessment has led to the identification of the following general and specific objectives, which are consistent with those of the action plan.

3.1. General objective: Enhancing the fairness of the tax system

A first important aim is to enhance the fairness of the tax system by addressing some of the root causes of corporate tax avoidance by multinational companies. The specific objectives supporting this general goal are to

• (i) significantly reduce cross-border tax planning possibilities;

• (ii) create a more level playing field between domestic and multinational companies;

• (iii) ensure that companies pay a fair share of the tax burden; and

• (iv) enhance general tax payer morale, which is currently seriously undermined by a strong perception that international players are largely escaping taxation.

3.2. General objective: Stimulating growth and investment

The improvement of the business environment by removing single market tax obstacles was the central objective of the 2011 CCCTB proposal. This objective remains important in order to maintain or even enhance the competitiveness of companies in the EU and is reflected in the 10 Commission priorities which put an emphasis on strengthening jobs,

growth and investment as well as the single market. 41 The specific objectives to support

this goal are to

• (i) significantly simplify within the EU the currently highly complex international system of corporate taxation to reduce compliance costs and administrative burden; and

• (ii) eliminate double taxation risks within the EU and remove still existing discriminations and restrictions.

Supported by lessons learned following the financial crisis and given the still modest and uneven economic recovery, two more objectives have been identified that a reform of the corporate tax system for the EU should deliver:

• (iii) provide an approach to profit taxation that does not distort investment and financing decisions; and

• (iv) create more incentives to invest in the EU, inter alia by supporting R&D and

innovation to safeguard and enhance current welfare levels. 42 In light of the current

underinvestment in business R&D (compared to its importance for innovation, productivity and economic growth), a minimum requirement should be that the

preferred option maintains the current tax incentives for R&D expenses. Incentives going beyond the current levels in the EU need to be balanced against the revenue costs for providing such incentives.

41 The 10 priorities are summarized here: https://ec.europa.eu/priorities/index_en .

42 This is in coherence with the Commission's objective to stimulate more investment and jobs in Europe under the Investment Plan.

One should note that there is a trade-off between the general objectives. Notably, reducing costs for companies and fostering investment by more attractive allowances and deductions could in some cases be difficult to reconcile with ensuring effective taxation by reducing tax planning opportunities. In addition, it can also impact tax collection. Therefore the two general objectives need to be balanced. The objective to stimulate growth and investment needs to be put in coherence with the objective of enhancing the fairness of the tax system and should not result in more tax planning opportunities. Notably, experiences with some of the measures taken at national level to tackle the debt bias and to promote R&D point to the need for a specific anti-abuse design. Provided that due attention is given to the design and anti-abuse framework, reforms in these areas would actually provide for an opportunity to tackle specific tax avoidance channels. For example, addressing the debt bias could remove opportunities for groups operating crossborder to shift profit via the debt instrument.

  • 4. 
    P OLICY OPTIONS

In line with the action plan of June 2015 and the existing CCCTB proposal, the main option for a policy proposal will centre on the CCCTB as proposed and discussed in the Council since 2011 (see Box 1). This is in the following referred to as the 'central scenario'. The impact of having an interim stage without consolidation and apportionment, but with the possibility of some form of cross-border loss relief has also been examined (Sections 4.5 and 5.5). A key element within the options for a CCCTB is its scope (Sections 4.2 and 5.2), determining which taxpayers should be subject to mandatory application of the CCCTB and which taxpayers could be allowed to opt into the system. Further, there are naturally many different options to choose from for the design of the CCCTB. Most of the relevant design elements have been evaluated thoroughly in the preparations for the 2011 proposal. Discussions have subsequently progressed in Council. The present impact assessment therefore focusses on assessing options for new elements that were not yet discussed in the earlier proposal: measures to tackle the debt bias (Sections 4.3 and 5.3) and R&D tax incentives (Sections 4.4 and 5.4). Table 2 gives an overview of the intervention logic by linking problems, objectives and policy options as well as providing the context for the initiative.

Table 2: Intervention logic

Policy options

Problems Objectives CCCTB Scope (mandatory Debt bias R&D CCCTB) solution incentives

General Objective 1: Enhancing the fairness of the tax system x

Reduce cross-border tax planning x

Level playing field between domestic

Cross-border and multinational companies x

corporate tax avoidance

Ensure that companies pay a fair share

of the tax burden x

Enhance general tax payer morale x

General Objective 2: Stimulating growth and investment x x x x

Single market: tax obstacles, Reduce compliance costs and administrative burden x

compliance costs Eliminate double taxation risks and remove still existing

discriminations and restrictions x

Debt bias in taxation Taxation neutrality for investment and financing decisions x

Underinvestment in R&D Creating more incentives to invest in the EU x x

Context: Globalization, changing business models with increasingly mobile profits and tax bases, current international tax rules struggle with

determining the place of taxation, little tax coordination at the international level creates incentives for governments to engage in tax competition, impact on

distribution on tax burden and fairness

Source: European Commission

The analysis focuses on the new elements that are added to the original proposal, but all comparisons are always made against the 'no CCCTB' baseline scenario. Note also that the additional options (debt bias solution, R&D incentives, etc.) are analysed here as separate policy interventions, whereas they are in reality provisions of the corporate tax base included in the CCCTB proposal and not separate proposals on their own.

4.1. Option 1: No further EU action

In case of no further EU action, the expected evolution of the current situation is as described in the baseline scenario. Notably, the CCCTB would not be implemented, but the Anti-Tax Avoidance Package is implemented and eventually public country-bycountry reporting by large multinational entities will be in place. The root problems linked to current international practices for the distribution of taxable profits will largely remain. Differences in the treatment of debt- and equity-financing are likely to continue to push up indebtedness and bear on growth. Differences in the treatment of debt and equity across Member States will continue to offer tax planning opportunities. Differences in R&D tax incentives will continue to prevent the emergence of a single market for research, and promote tax competition strategies for the location of intellectual property, without increasing R&D activities. As a consequence, sociallyinefficient levels of R&D may remain. Overall, as the internationalisation of the global economy is expected to continue, it is likely that tax avoidance strategies will continue to be sought after. In the long term, a shift to those avoidance strategies that are not at the centre of the more recent policy proposals can be expected. Even new strategies might be created, circumventing the new anti-avoidance rules and other measures that most likely will be in place in the near future.

4.2. Option 2: CCCTB with a scope definition

To keep the exposition reasonably simple, only the main options for the scope are outlined below. Where relevant, sub-options on various design questions will be discussed in Section 5.

4.2.1. Option 2a: Optional for all firms

Under this option, the CCCTB would be fully optional. Given the magnitude of tax savings that are currently achievable for those companies that use tax avoidance strategies most aggressively (see evidence in Table 1), it is unlikely that potential CCCTB benefits such as reduced compliance costs, enhanced R&D benefits or crossborder loss offset suffice to make these firms opt into the CCCTB. Consequently, a fully optional approach would not effectively fight tax avoidance and is thus not suited to enhancing the fairness of the tax system. This option is therefore not considered further in the analysis of impacts in Section 4.

4.2.2. Option 2b: Compulsory application for a defined set of firms and possibility to opt

in for all others

This option would make the application of the CCCTB compulsory for a defined set of companies, while giving all others the option to apply the CCCTB. The criteria for defining the compulsory element should ideally capture companies which are most relevant in the corporate tax avoidance context to comprehensively address corporate tax avoidance in the EU and not introduce any undue selectivity. Several criteria can theoretically be envisaged, alone or combined: (i) a sectorial approach, (ii) an approach targeting multinational entities via a definition of cross-border groups and (iii) a size approach.

4.2.3. Option 2c: Compulsory application for a defined set of firms without possibility to

opt in for other firms

This option would make the application of the CCCTB compulsory for certain companies, but would not allow other companies to opt into the CCCTB system. While such an approach would be in line with the objective of fighting tax avoidance in the EU, this option is clearly problematic vis-à-vis the equally important objectives of stimulating growth and investment and creating a level playing field. If the CCCTB delivers on its promise to provide for a simple corporate tax system which would reduce compliance costs and double taxation risks in the cross-border context, preventing some companies from applying the system is not appropriate. Indeed, to the extent that the CCCTB could provide more attractive design and compliance features than national tax systems, such an approach may imply granting an advantage on a selective basis which would be contrary to State aid principles. It may also raise concerns in terms of discrimination under the fundamental freedoms. Finally, stakeholders who expressed their views widely support a possibility to opt in. About 60% of respondents are in favour and only 9% reject the idea. Some of the opponents explain their rejection with concerns about tax planning possibilities. Not granting the possibility to opt-in is therefore not retained as an option in the analysis of impacts in Section 5.

4.2.4. Option 2d: Compulsory application for all firms

This option would replace all existing national CIT systems with the single set of rules provided by the CCCTB. Member States would continue to determine tax rates at national level. Thus all corporations in the EU, irrespective of their size, group structure or cross-border activity would have to apply the CCCTB.

4.3. Option 3: Solutions to address the debt bias

4.3.1. Option 3a: No debt bias action

The no-action case assumes that the CCCTB does not provide any specific measure to comprehensively address the debt bias. This implies that, as in the 2011 proposal, equity costs are not deductible while interest expenses remain deductible, though with limitations (notably those included in the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive).

4.3.2. Option 3b: Nondeductibility of interest expenses

Disallowing the deductibility of interest expenses would align the treatment of debt and

equity costs. 43 With full non-deductibility of interest expenses, interest limitation rules

would become obsolete.

4.3.3. Option 3c: Allowance for corporate equity (ACE)

An allowance for corporate equity grants a defined return for equity which is deductible from the tax base. The defined interest rate is usually close to or linked to a risk-free

reference rate such as the interest rates of government bonds. 44 Since the allowance is

computed by multiplying a defined rate on a definition of equity, an ACE does not necessarily achieve full financing neutrality between debt and equity, but moves in any case the system closer to neutrality.

The allowance can be designed in several ways. First, the allowance can apply to the total stock of equity (stock-based) or to the difference between current equity and equity at a specific date in the past (incremental-based). Second, the level of the defined rate can vary with the reference interest rate. Third, the design can include anti-abuse measures to avoid cascading of the benefits along the ownership structure of the corporate group.

43 This option resembles a 1992 proposal from the U.S. Department of Treasury, called a Comprehensive

Business Income Tax (CBIT). However, the CBIT is more far-reaching as it complements the nondeductibility of interest expenses with the non-taxation of interest income, an element which goes beyond the EU's legal power to act.

44 The proposal goes back to a contribution by Devereux and Freeman (1991). It has been tested in practice and with different designs. Currently, Belgium, Italy and more recently, Cyprus apply an ACE. Austria, Latvia and Croatia also experienced an ACE. Portugal has an ACE for its SMEs (under eligibility conditions) and is considering extending its scope. Other countries such as Turkey also currently have an ACE.

4.3.4. Option 3d: Allowance for growth and investment (AGI)

The allowance for growth and investment is one specific version of an ACE. The AGI is incremental with a moving reference date in the past. This means it is granted only for the sum of equity increases over a specific period (e.g. 10 years in the past). Also, the AGI foresees rules so that new capital can only benefit once from the deductibility.

4.3.5. Option 3e: Allowance for corporate capital (ACC)

Under this option, companies may deduct a defined return on total capital, i.e. the sum of debt and equity. At the same time, it is no longer permitted to deduct actual interest expenses. Since there is only one rate applied to debt and equity, this option achieves full

financing choice neutrality. 45 The need for a limitation rule for the allowance would have

to be examined. So far, it has not been implemented in practice. The same considerations in terms of stock versus incremental, the reference rate and the possible anti-abuse measures apply as for the ACE and the AGI.

4.3.6. Option 3f: Cost of capital allowance (CoCA)

The cost of capital allowance combines a defined interest on capital at the corporate level with the inclusion in the profit of the shareholder of an amount equivalent to the ACE

deduction obtained by the corporation and instead of actual dividends and interest. 46 The

CoCA is a far-reaching proposal that includes changes in the taxation of capital income at the level of individuals. The option for a CoCA is not retained in the analysis of impacts in Section 5 as it is too far-reaching. At corporate level, the effects of the CoCA are identical to those of the ACC. The same considerations in terms of stock versus incremental, the reference rate and the possible anti-abuse measures apply as for the ACE and the AGI.

4.4. Option 4: Options to incentivise R&D

R&D tax incentives reduce the tax burden on R&D activities. They can target R&D inputs by supporting R&D related expenditure. Such measures either reduce the tax base by granting a deductible allowance or they directly reduce the amount of tax to be paid in form of a tax credit. Support measures can also be based on output, i.e. income generated by R&D outcomes such as patents. The latter offer reduced rates on R&D income.

4.4.1. Option 4a: No further action on R&D

The no-action option assumes that, as in the 2011 proposal, all R&D expenses would be expensed immediately for tax purposes. However, to reflect concerns expressed by Member States in Council, it is also assumed that capital expenses on R&D buildings would not be expensed immediately, but depreciated in the same way as other

45 An ACC was first analysed by Boadway and Bruce (1984).

46 This system was proposed by Kleinbard (2015).

buildings. 47 No national R&D tax incentives would apply any more for companies

applying the CCCTB.

4.4.2. Option 4b: Granting tax incentives for R&D expenses

Under this option, the CCCTB would offer additional allowances or tax credits on R&D expenses, replicating tax incentives applicable under the national systems.

4.4.2.1. Additional allowance for R&D expenses

An additional allowance decreases the tax base by deducting more than 100% of R&D

expenditure. 48 For example, a company could deduct an additional allowance of 50% of

their R&D expenditure on top of the full deductibility of R&D costs, i.e. 150% in total.

The effective level of generosity of the additional allowance varies with the applicable corporate tax rate.

4.4.2.2. Tax credit for R&D expenses

Tax credits and additional allowances are economically very similar. The operational difference is that tax credits reduce directly the tax bill and therefore do not vary with the tax rate. However, tax credits go beyond the scope of the common base. Member States would give a tax credit after the computation of the tax liability which would be in opposition to the spirit of the CCCTB. By granting a tax reduction after the application of formula apportionment they would not ensure a level playing field for R&D in the EU

and could induce harmful competition between Member States. 49 Therefore this option is

not retained.

4.4.3. Option 4c: Granting tax incentives for income from intellectual property

Output-related incentives apply reduced rates to income generated by R&D, i.e. earned from exploiting intellectual property (patent boxes). The empirical evidence suggests that input-related incentives are more effective than patent boxes in stimulating R&D

investments. 50

Moreover, patent boxes have in recent years given rise to concerns of harmful tax competition. First, intangible assets play an important role in profit shifting as their

location can be tax sensitive and can lead to large revenue losses. 51 Evidence from ZEW

(2016c) as summarised in Table 1 shows the considerable decrease in effective tax rates

47 R&D expenses on buildings and land account for only a small share of total business R&D (around 5%

according to OECD estimates) and are therefore not expected to materially affect incentives to invest in R&D. The largest part of R&D spending is for skilled labour which also generates the highest spillovers.

48 Note that the term "additional allowance" in the context of R&D refers to the amount of tax incentives

granted on top of immediate expensing of R&D expenditures, i.e. an immediate deduction of 100%. In the literature different terms are used to describe this additional allowance, e.g. enhanced allowance, bonus allowance, super allowance or super deduction. In the following, the term additional allowance will be used.

49 A detailed description of the formula apportionment is provided in annex VII.

50 See CPB (2014).

51 See Griffith et al. (2014).

that multinational groups can achieve by exploiting patent box regimes. Second, patent

boxes do not stimulate increases in R&D activity. 52 Third, there is no clear rationale for

using patent boxes as a means of stimulating innovation, as they do not appear to address any specific market failure. Instead, they award additional tax benefits to a successful innovation that already enjoys intellectual property protection. Research efforts that are not patentable with potentially higher social spillovers are less attractive and thus become indirectly discriminated. Finally, the compliance costs required to directly link R&D expenses to individual patentable efforts are significant and extremely complex for businesses and tax administrations.

All in all, this option does not only go contrary to the objective of reducing tax avoidance and improving the fairness of the tax system, but also against the objective of stimulating additional research and innovation and simplifying the tax system. It is therefore not

retained for further analysis. 53

4.5. Option 5: Staged approach

Recognising the likely difficulties to adopt the CCCTB in one step, the June 2015 action plan announced that consolidation and formula apportionment would be postponed until the common base has been agreed and implemented. This impact assessment therefore assesses the implications of such a staged approach. The key question concerns the granting of some form of cross-border loss relief in the absence of consolidation.

It is useful to note here that there will be no differentiation between stage 1 (CCTB) and stage 2 (CCCTB) regarding the scope and the definition of the tax base (including the debt bias solution and the R&D incentives). The directive on a common base would be implemented as a first step and then be amended in stage 2 via a CCCTB directive to incorporate consolidation and formula apportionment. The base definitions as such do not change in stage 2.

4.5.1. Option 5a: Common base without cross-border loss relief

This option focusses on securing the common tax base at a first stage. This would involve agreeing to a common set of corporate tax rules for computing the tax base of companies without possibility for multinational entities to offset losses in one Member State with profits in another Member State.

4.5.2. Option 5b: Common base with cross-border loss relief

With the aim to strengthen EU competitiveness, the common base could include a mechanism of (partial) cross-border loss relief with subsequent recapture. Taxpayers would be entitled to temporarily take into account the losses incurred by their immediate subsidiaries and permanent establishments situated in other Member States.

52 See Alstadsæter et al. (2015).

53 To prevent the harmfulness of these schemes, an agreement was reached in the OECD and in the EU on the approach to be taken to ensure that there is a clear link between the tax advantage being granted under the patent box and a firm’s R&D activities ('nexus approach'). However, this does not mean that these schemes are effective in raising R&D efforts.

Table 3: Options retained for further analysis

Option 1 Options 2 Options 3 Options 4 Options 5

Basic choice for action Scope Addressing the debt Ensuring incentives Staged bias for R&D approach

No action (baseline Tax treatment of equity

scenario, i.e. assuming as currently in place in R&D tax regimes as they

implementation of Member States; interest currently exist in treatment aligned with Member States

ATAP / CbCR) ATAP

CCTB without

CCCTB Optional for all No action (treatment as No action (treatment as firms in the 2011 proposal) in the 2011 proposal) cross-border loss

relief

Mandatory for some CCTB with

set of firms; opt-in No interest deductibility Enhanced allowance for for others R&D expenses

cross-border loss relief

Mandatory for some

set of firms; no opt Allowance for corporate Tax credit for R&D

in for others equity expenses

Mandatory for all Allowance for growth Tax incentives for

firms and investment income from Intellectual Property

Allowance for corporate

capital

Cost of Capital

Allowance

Source: European Commission

Note: ATAP = Anti-Tax Avoidance Package;

CbCR = Country-by-Country Reporting; strike-through marks options which are not retained.

  • 5. 
    A NALYSIS OF IMPACTS OF THE OPTIONS

This section assesses the options outlined above in terms of their effectiveness and coherence in reaching the specific objectives, which contribute to the general objectives of enhancing fairness and stimulating growth and investment. Fairness of the tax system is measured mainly against the effectiveness of the option to limit tax avoidance in the future. The assessment involves a qualitative evaluation on the suitability of options to prevent the most relevant cross-border tax planning strategies, as well as a quantification of the impact on profit shifting in the EU. Stimulating growth and investment is assessed vis-à-vis the specific objectives outlined in Section 3.2. Simplification is achieved to the extent that complexity is effectively reduced. The impact on financing distortions is assessed in terms of the change in the debt bias, which is measured here as the difference in the cost of capital of an investment if financed by equity or debt. Investment distortions are measured in terms of the impact on the average cost of capital of investments. The main options are also assessed in terms of their impact on the economy in a general equilibrium model. Main variables looked at include GDP, investment, employment and wages and welfare. Finally, the section discusses the expected impact on tax revenues and on the burden for companies and administrations as a result of implementing the different options.

The coherence assessment focusses on evaluating whether fairness and tax avoidance objectives are indeed not achieved at the expense of stimulating growth and investment and vice versa.

To reduce complexity, the assessment is presented in sequential steps. This separation of option dimensions is justified as there are no relevant interdependencies between them. Other possible interdependencies are discussed whenever appropriate; otherwise the independence between different option dimensions is explained in the following subsections. Sections 5.1 and 5.2 focus on the basic choice of 'no action' versus implementation of a CCCTB and the options on the scope of the application. Assuming implementation of the CCCTB with the preferred scope option, Sections 5.3 and 5.4 assess the open design issues related to debt bias and R&D incentives. Finally, Section 5.5 assesses the impact of introducing the CCCTB in two steps, with an initial period without consolidation, but possibly with some form of cross-border loss relief.

Box 2: Formula apportionment

The distribution of revenues based on a formula is an important element of the CCCTB proposal and its impact was analysed in the 2011 impact assessment (see also annexes V and VIII). It concluded to allocate the consolidated tax base to a 'group member A' according to the following formula:

𝐴𝐴

Share A = � 1 𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 1 𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆

𝐴𝐴 𝑁𝑁𝑃𝑃 𝑃𝑃𝑜𝑜 𝑆𝑆𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴

3 𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 +

1

3 � 2 + 𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 +

1

2 𝑁𝑁𝑃𝑃 𝑃𝑃𝑜𝑜 𝑆𝑆𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 � +

1 𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴

3 𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 � .

∗ 𝐶𝐶𝑃𝑃𝑛𝑛 ′ 𝑑𝑑 𝑇𝑇𝑆𝑆𝑇𝑇 𝐵𝐵𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆

Aside from the extensive work by the CCCTB Working Group and consultations with stakeholders, three specific pieces of analysis were included in the impact assessment in order to compare the impact of different formulas: (i) a survey of multinational entities on compliance costs: (ii) impact of variations in the formula on the distribution of tax bases across countries, using the Amadeus and ORBIS databases; and (iii) the CORTAX study, which examined formula apportionment within the context of a wider analysis aiming to quantify the impacts of alternative policy options. The formula was evaluated against four criteria: 1. Simplicity for taxpayers and administrations; 2. Difficult to manipulate, i.e. no easy relocation of factors to exploit tax-rate differentials across the EU; 3. Fair and equitable distribution of the tax base; 4. No negative impact on tax competition. More details on the rationale for the formula that was chosen can be found in Annex V: Formula apportionment.

Figure 7 shows the sequence of the analysis. To justify this sequential approach it is required that the preferred options for the scope, for the debt bias solution and for R&D incentives do not change if the choice of options changes for the other dimensions. Based on the available analytical evidence and qualitative arguments this can be assumed with relative confidence. For example, the choice of a solution for addressing the debt bias seems independent of the choice for the scope or of the choice for the R&D incentives.

In contrast, this does not mean that the choice of each dimension does not affect the final outcome. In other words, the economic impact of a preferred option (for example to address the debt bias) might very well change if options in another dimension change (for example the mandatory scope). For example, implementing an AGI for all companies or only a selection of them will have different economic impacts. However, the important point is that the ranking of the preferred options seems to be independent from the

choices made elsewhere. 54

54 However, it should be made clear that it is not possible to quantify in all cases the exact impacts due to the limitations of the analytical model, even if this latter is considered state-of-the-art in corporate taxation analysis in an international context. Based on the partial analysis that is available on the combination of certain options and based on additional quantitative arguments outlined in the analysis

Figure 7: Analytical approach – sequence of analysis

Source: European Commission

5.1. Baseline vs CCCTB

This section compares the CCCTB (option 1b) with the baseline scenario (option 1a), assuming that the CCCTB will be either (i) mandatory for some set of firms with the possibility to opt in for others or (ii) mandatory for all firms. To keep the exposition reasonably simple, this section discusses the case of a CCCTB without any specific measures to address the debt bias or to ensure sufficient incentives for R&D. Since there is a certain degree of overlap of the present assessment with the impact assessment of the 2011 proposal, the main conclusions of the 2011 assessment have been summarised in annex VIII.

5.1.1. Fairness impacts

Despite the progress at EU level in coordinating a stronger anti-abuse framework, it is clear that these new rules alone do not address comprehensively the roots of the problem, particularly in the long term. The inherent conflict remains between corporate taxation rules determined at national levels on one hand and an increasingly integrated economy

below, one can be confident that the principal choices (i.e. limiting the mandatory scope to large firms, opting for an allowance for growth and investment to address the debt bias, providing additional allowance for R&D expenses) would not change even if a complete model that could capture all the interactions were available.

and mobile profits on the other hand. As such, there is a risk that the new anti-abuse framework addresses only a selection of avoidance strategies, so that companies over time would adjust their behaviour towards other planning strategies. Not only would this entail the need for new anti-abuse rules and an ever more complex system, it would also mean that tax planning multinational entities will keep their undue advantages vis-à-vis purely domestic firms.

Due to the common rules for determining the tax base combined with full consolidation, the CCCTB would by and large eliminate profit-shifting possibilities within the EU for those companies subject to mandatory application. Notably, aggressive tax planning by exploiting mismatches and making use of patent boxes would no longer be possible, provided that due attention is given to definitions of central concepts such as debt, interest expenses, profits and dividends. Whereas exploiting tax differentials via intragroup loans or transfer pricing would no longer be beneficial. Effectively, the most

relevant aggressive tax planning strategies would be addressed within the EU. 55

Incentives for tax planning remain however relevant vis-à-vis third countries. Therefore, the CCCTB is equipped with a broad set of anti-avoidance measures. As discussed above, many of these measures are already adopted with the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive. Hence, anti-abuse rules addressing tax avoidance involving third countries would be harmonised with a CCCTB which leaves companies with less room to shop for

the most attractive regime(s) in the EU. 56 Limited opportunities would remain in relation

to differences in withholding tax regimes between EU Member States and third countries, with respect to factor allocation under the formula apportionment regime and, if the mandatory application is not extended to all firms, with respect to those companies or

parts of a company group that are not subject to the CCCTB. 57 Also, transfer pricing

remains an issue between the EU and third countries.

In the general equilibrium model used to analyse the economic impacts of a CCCTB

reform, 58 multinational entities have the possibility to shift profits within their group via transfer pricing. 59 Table 4 below compares the impact of profit shifting on tax bases in

the baseline case and in the CCCTB case (compulsory for multinational entities). The table shows the percent changes in the tax base due to intra-group profit shifting from and into EU Member States. The starting point is the hypothetical tax base that would occur if transfer pricing was not available to multinational entities. In the model, which covers the EU-28, the US and Japan, the CCCTB results in the complete elimination of any outward shifting of profits from EU Member States. Inward shifting is also largely eliminated although some inward shifting from the high-tax countries US and Japan remains. CORTAX currently cannot simulate other aggressive tax planning techniques. To the extent that these are no longer possible or beneficial within the EU under the

55 See Ramboll et al. (2015) for a description of those tax planning strategies.

56 The relevance of this point is underlined by the findings in ZEW (2016c).

57 See annex V for a discussion.

58 See annex IV (part 1) for a detailed description of model.

59 CORTAX does not model other tax planning strategies, which are often based on specific regimes offered in national tax systems or certain mismatches between national systems. Therefore the analysis of the profit shifting impact is stylised and summarised via the transfer pricing channel. In addition, the analysis only covers profit shifting within the EU, the US and Japan. Consequently, the figures presented here are not comparable with the estimates presented in Section 2 on the possible tax revenue costs of tax avoidance.

CCCTB, notably strategies using mismatches, intra-group loans and patent boxes, similar relative impacts can be expected.

Overall, in terms of effectively addressing tax avoidance, the CCCTB has very clear advantages compared to the 'no action' scenario.

Table 4: Impact on intra-group profit shifting

Baseline CCCTB Change

Outward Inward Outward Inward Outward Inward

Average* EU-28 -1.51% 5.51% 0.00% 0.96% -100% -82.5%

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

Note: The values indicate changes in percent to the theoretical tax base without intra-group profit shifting. *Average refers to the weighted EU average of the individual country values.

Due to the reduced tax planning opportunities, governments will face fewer difficulties in ensuring a fair contribution to tax collection from the corporate sector. Under a formula apportionment mechanism as described in box 2 (but in the absence of rate harmonisation) planning opportunities may still theoretically arise because of the incentive to relocate the apportionment factors included in the formula and hence attribute the largest possible share of their profit to low-tax Member States. For instance, multinational entities may engage in 'factor shifting' operations by structuring sales through 'independent' distributors located in low-tax Member States. However, the literature confirms that the envisaged formula apportionment system is much less prone to such artificial arrangements than the current system because shifts of real factors are

generally more difficult and costly to do than shifts of book profits. 60 The application of

anti-abuse and related provisions in the CCCTB further reduces this possible avoidance issue.

Moreover, the optimal location of factors depends on many determinants other than taxes (such as infrastructure quality, availability of skilled work). In addition, the possibility to opt into the system for companies outside the mandatory scope mitigates risks of tax rate competition, as a country that lowers the tax rate applicable to the CCCTB would risk a larger deterioration of revenues as more and more companies would opt in. It is therefore expected that the problems that Member States face today with mobile tax bases and the ensuing tax competition will not persist within the EU under the CCCTB with formula apportionment.

The effective reduction of tax planning activities is expected to have a positive impact on taxpayer morale. Over the past years, more and more large-scale tax avoidance cases have become publicly known. This is damaging as it may impact taxpayer compliance more generally. It is known that social norms may influence the compliance behaviour of taxpayers. To the extent that tax avoidance cases reveal poor tax ethics, i.e. a poor sense of responsibility for contributing a fair share to society, this might negatively impact on the ethics of other taxpayers. Moreover, taxpayers without tax planning opportunities may perceive this as unfair and feel a moral justification to not fully comply with their obligations. Indeed, several studies support the view that a perception of unfairness in

60 See Annex V: Formula apportionment.

taxation negatively impacts tax compliance behaviour or at least the willingness to

cooperate with tax authorities. 61

5.1.2. Economic impacts

To assess the economic impact of various options, the CORTAX model was used. CORTAX is a computable general equilibrium model, allowing state-of-the-art analysis of corporate tax reforms by incorporating key features such as multinational profit shifting, investment decisions, loss compensation and the debt-equity choice of firms. The model includes the direct and indirect effects of all domestic labour and capital markets. It covers the 28 countries of the European Union, the U.S., Japan and a tax haven. The CORTAX simulations assess the impact of the CCCTB on a set of main economic variables such as investment, employment and wages, GDP and welfare. It is assumed that the CCCTB is implemented in a budget-neutral manner, notably by

compensating changes in the corporate tax base by changes in the CIT rate. 62 Results can

be made available for two basic assumptions on the set of firms applying the CCCTB: either all firms or only multinational entities. The assumption that all multinational entities apply the CCCTB fits, within the logic of the model, to a wide range of possible

definitions for the mandatory scope as long as domestic firms are not included. 63

Table 5 shows the results of implementing the CCCTB for multinationals only and for all firms (both compared to the baseline scenario). Whether applied to multinational entities only or to all firms, the CCCTB has positive effects on key economic variables. The cost of capital decrease and as a result investment increases. Employment and wages are also positively affected, as is GDP and welfare. The results for CCCTB for all firms are generally more positive, albeit the differences are marginal.

Table 5: Economic impact of the CCCTB (GDP-weighted EU average)

CCCTB – CCCTB – only multinational entities all firms

Cost of capital (change in percentage points) -0.04 -0.07

Investment 0.57 0.74

Wages 0.40 0.44

Employment 0.19 0.19

GDP 0.16 0.26

Welfare (change in % of GDP) 0.07 0.10

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

Notes: Changes are in % unless noted otherwise. All simulations are changes compared to the baseline scenario of no CCCTB

61 See the contributions by Fortin, Lacroix and Villeval (2007), Weber et al. (2014), Kirchler,

Niemirowski and Wearing (2006) and Torgler et al. (2008). 62 In more detail, the model adjusts ex-ante the corporate statutory tax rates to ensure ex-ante revenueneutrality

when the corporate tax base changes. The adjusted CIT rate is subject to an upper bound for of 37.5% and a lower bound of 10%. In addition, budget neutrality is ensured ex-post by a change in lump-sum transfers to the citizens (see JRC (2016) for the details).

63 More details on the model and the study that was performed by the Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016) are available in annex IV.

As a caveat, CORTAX does not permit a proper assessment on the level playing field between domestic firms and multinational entities. On the one hand, the closing of the most important cross-border tax planning channels is not properly reflected in the model. CORTAX captures profit shifting in a stylised way through transfer pricing via intragroup sales, but does not feature multinational entities exploiting mismatches, making use of patent boxes or saving taxes via intra-group loans. On the other hand, multinational groups in the model benefit considerably from consolidation. This is mostly because they are all active in all 28 Member States, which makes it very likely that a loss occurred in one Member State can be offset against profits in other Member States. Thus, the model tends to capture more the positive features for multinational entities while the loss of tax planning opportunities is reflected only partially. In contrast, the possible positive impact on domestic firms is not captured in the model. This is because CORTAX does not feature the opt-in choice of firms. In the 'only multinational entities' case, domestic firms are assumed to stay in their respective national system, which is broadly consistent within the logic of the model. In the 'all firms' case, domestic firms are all forced into the CCCTB. In both cases, there may be reasons that domestic firms would rather opt into/stay out of the CCCTB. For example, if for a domestic firm the CCCTB tax base is smaller compared to the national tax base and this advantage is not fully eliminated by a larger CCCTB tax rate, a domestic firm might choose the CCCTB. The CCCTB may also be attractive as it may be simpler to administer than the national system, notably due to the depreciation regime, which allows depreciating shortlife assets in a pool rather than individually.

Hence, the model may over-emphasise the positive impacts of the reform for multinational entities, whereas it may underestimate them for domestic firms. Moreover, this relative difference in the impacts is reinforced to the extent that domestic firms and multinational entities compete against each other. As a result, the CORTAX simulations show a large increase in production of multinational entities and a large decrease in production of domestic firms, as reported in Table 6. Due to the caveats explained above, and notably since the model does not feature the possibility to opt in for domestic firms, the magnitude of the estimated impacts on production cannot be considered realistic. It therefore does not seem justified to reject the proposal based on this result alone.

Table 6: Impact on production by category of firm

Category of firm CCCTB – CCCTB – only multinational entities all firms

Domestic* -9.89 -12.22

Multinational headquarter 9.59 11.03

Multinational subsidiary 19.39 25.95

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

Note: Impact is given as EU-28 weighted average of the change in %. All simulations are changes compared to the baseline scenario of no CCCTB. *Domestic firms in the 'only multinational entities case' are assumed to not opt in, even if in reality they may prefer to do so.

A sensitivity analysis based on a number of variations in the assumptions has been conducted. The variations that have been considered include different depreciation regimes, variation in the capital-labour substitutability, reduced compliance cost savings under the CCCTB and compensating changes in tax bases by modifying labour taxes instead of corporate income tax. All variations yield similar results as in the central case, pointing to the robustness of the findings, namely positive economic impacts.

Impacts on tax revenue

The CORTAX simulations also allow for some first considerations on the impact on tax revenues although the model cannot simulate all transmission channels. The available simulations point to a small decrease in total tax revenues for the EU-28 of 0.08% of GDP, corresponding to about EUR 11 billion. This results from a decrease in EU-28 corporate tax revenues by about EUR 36 billion partly compensated by increases in the collection of other taxes by about EUR 25 billion. These tax increases are due to increased economic activity and better employment that respectively boost consumption and labour tax bases.

These figures should be put in perspective with the potential gain in corporate tax revenues due to the reduction in several forms of corporate tax avoidance. As discussed in the previous subsection, the CORTAX model captures the impact from reduced transfer pricing activities (which are eliminated in the model), but it does not capture the removal of patent boxes, the removal of hybrid mismatches and the elimination of profit shifting via intra-group debt shifts. A recent study commissioned by the European Parliamentary Research Service finds that the corporate tax revenue losses due to tax avoidance would amount to about EUR 50-70 billion in the EU. It is however difficult to assess the share of this amount due to transfer pricing and the share due to other

channels. 64

Moreover, interpreting these values is difficult as a number of factors impact on revenues. Most importantly, the model assumes that governments set the CIT rate for the CCCTB in order to compensate for changes in the rules to compute the corporate tax base. This is a technical assumption as national governments would be free to adjust tax rates in other ways. More details and a discussion of other factors that drive the impact on tax revenues are provided in annex XII.

Impact on administrative burden

The effectiveness of the CCCTB in simplifying the currently highly complex international system of corporate taxation, reducing compliance costs and double taxation and removing discriminations and restrictions in cross-border situations, has been

demonstrated in the 2011 impact assessment. 65 To which extent the CCCTB would be

made mandatory is of little relevance for these impacts as companies or company groups which would gain the most from reduced compliance costs are expected to opt into the system. The differences in national R&D incentives schemes (as illustrated in annex XI) are a good example to illustrate the potential for simplification. These differences can lead to high compliance cost for businesses that conduct their R&D cross-border or engage in transnational cooperations on R&D projects for example through joint ventures.

As explained in annex VII, tax compliance costs remain an important burden for businesses and their reduction is a major advantage of the CCCTB compared to the

64 Available studies on the tax revenue impact from transfer pricing do not give a clear indication. The staff working document accompanying the June action plan includes a summary discussion of the available studies (SWD/2015/121).

65 See annex VIII for an overview.

baseline. The 2011 impact assessment estimated compliance costs for large companies to amount to about 2% of taxes paid, while for SMEs the estimate was about 30% of taxes paid. In absolute terms, compliance costs were estimated to increase with cross-border activity and with increasing number of subsidiaries. The compliance cost levels and their structure do not seem to have changed considerably in recent years. A recent review of compliance tax studies (Eichfelder and Vaillancourt, 2014) shows for the period from 1984 to 2014 that compliance costs remain largely stable over time. Existing differences between different estimates are rather due to different methodologies applied to measure

the costs. 66

One could expect that compliance requirements have rather slightly increased since the 2011 assessment. In fact, tax reform data show that numerous CIT reforms took place after the crisis and many measures were directed at reinforcing the international antiabuse

framework. 67 In the light of this, the reduction of compliance costs when setting up

an additional subsidiary under the CCCTB remains a major advantage: Time costs for setting up a new subsidiary in a Member State were estimated to decrease 62-67% for the CCCTB. Focussing on recurring costs, i.e. ignoring one-off switching costs, the 2011 impact assessment estimated a decrease in time spent on compliance activities by 8% for

the CCCTB. 68 Based on these time reductions one could endeavour a rough calculation

of the order of total cost savings that would result under the CCCTB. If 5% of mediumsized companies expand abroad, a one-off cost saving of around EUR 1 billion could be expected. If all multinational entities apply the CCCTB recurring compliance costs could go down by about EUR 0.8 billion.

Tax administrations will benefit from reduced dealings with transfer pricing issues and a reduced 'case number' to the extent that the tax affairs of a company group is mainly dealt with by the administration of the Member State where the parent resides. However, if the CCCTB is not made mandatory for all firms, the burden for national administrations may go up slightly due to the required maintenance of two parallel systems. Also, there might be requirements to set-up new IT and communication systems between Member States to ensure a consistent enforcement and application of the CCCTB.

5.1.3. Stakeholder views

Most of the stakeholders (38%) believe that the CCCTB can be an effective tool against aggressive tax planning and at the same time retain attractiveness to businesses. This includes a majority of enterprises, driven by the views of SMEs, 54% of which agree with this view. Another 22% of stakeholders have a more nuanced opinion. A number of them give a qualified approval, i.e. attaching certain conditions; others point to the original motivation of removing single market barriers, which in their view should

66 The Commission services commissioned a study (Ramboll Management Consulting et al., 2013) on methodologies to measure compliance cost in 2013 which explains in detail the existing methods as well as the related caveats.

67 The Tax Reform Report 2015 describes the very recent anti-avoidance measures taken by Member States in the 2014 and 2015 (Section 1.5.2 of the report). For example, several Member States introduced or strengthened general or specific anti-avoidance provisions. Four Member States reinforced their transfer pricing rules, in particular by extending reporting requirements. Controlled Foreign-Company rules were introduced or tightened as were interest limitation rules.

68 See annex VII for a more detailed analysis of compliance costs.

remain the main focus. Some 17% of respondents do not believe in the effectiveness of the CCCTB against aggressive tax planning. Often they point to other initiatives against tax avoidance and/or do not find the CCCTB to be a proportionate measure.

5.1.4. Preferred option

Overall, the CCCTB (option 1b) is preferable over the alternative of taking no action (option 1a). The anticipated effects of enhancing fairness via reduced corporate tax avoidance, ensuring a fair tax contribution from the corporate sector, a more level playing field among companies and the expected positive impacts on taxpayer morale are critical, even if not all of them are quantifiable. This is also in line with the views of a majority of stakeholders. In addition, small positive economic impacts are expected through the removal of single market tax obstacles. Both the business environment and the labour market are positively affected. Overall, welfare is expected to increase slightly. The removal of tax obstacles is also expected to remove existing distortions between domestic and cross-border investments and enhance incentives for cross-border investments within the EU and form outside the EU.

Moreover, the administrative burden for companies operating cross-border is expected to reduce significantly. The burden for national administrations is expected to go down if the CCCTB is made mandatory for all firms. If not, the required maintenance of two parallel systems in case the CCCTB is not made mandatory for all companies could raise the costs for administrations.

Table 7 assesses the performance of the CCCTB vis-à-vis the no action scenario. The CCCTB performs better on most of the objectives.

Table 7: Assessment of impacts of the CCCTB (Option 1b)

CCCTB

Options central scenario

Enhancing the fairness of the yax system

Reduce cross-border tax planning opportunities ++

More level playing field for domestic and multinational companies ++

Companies pay a fair share of the tax burden ++

Enhance general taxpayer morale ++

Stimulating growth and investment

Simplify within the EU the currently highly complex international system of

corporate taxation ++

Eliminate double taxation risks within the EU and remove still existing

discriminations and restrictions ++

Approach to profit taxation that does not distort investment and financing decisions +/-

More incentives to invest in the EU +

Reduction in administrative burden for companies and administrations +

Source: European Commission

Note: The evaluation is based on a scale of five steps from very negative (- -) to very positive (++).

"0" indicates no change (i.e. neutrality).

5.2. Scope of the common consolidated base

This section will examine the options for the scope of the mandatory application, keeping in mind that it is motivated by the new objective of enhancing the fairness of the tax system by comprehensively addressing corporate tax avoidance. The available options are to make the application compulsory for all firms (option 2d) or to make it compulsory for some firms (the scope of which will be discussed) and to grant the possibility to opt in for other firms (option 2b). Full optionality (option 2a) as well as making the CCCTB mandatory for some set of firms without granting the possibility to opt in for other firms

(option 2c) have been discarded in Section 4.2. 69

5.2.1. Fairness impacts

To determine the mandatory set that is effective in capturing tax avoiders but proportionate at the same time, i.e. not imposing unjustified obligations, it is helpful to think of three mutually exclusive sets of firms. First, there are those firms that prefer the CCCTB over the current national systems. It is irrelevant whether the mandatory application applies to these firms as they will in any case benefit and therefore opt into the CCCTB. Second, there are firms that prefer the current national systems, not because they are currently employing tax avoidance strategies but because the net impact from the CCCTB is not positive for them, in the sense that it would increase their tax burden and they would not benefit sufficiently from reduced compliance costs. Third, there are firms that prefer to continue applying the current national systems because they benefit from tax avoidance strategies and this benefit is larger than any potential benefits from reduced tax compliance costs and the net impact of other changes.

It is not relevant whether the definition of the mandatory set covers firms in the first set, which in any case would opt-in. However, the aim should be that the definition captures the third set of firms and should only capture firms in the second set if there is a valid justification for requiring them to apply the CCCTB. Many firms in the second set are likely to be micro and small corporations. These smaller firms are unlikely to engage in

tax avoidance practices. Since a large share of them are active only domestically 70 , they

would also not be able to reap any of the potential benefits of the common base. In addition, 14 Member States currently apply specific regimes for the smallest corporations, not only in the form of reduced statutory rates, but in 11 of them also via

modified tax bases and/or relief from other taxes. 71 The mandatory for all option would

harmonise the tax treatment across all firms. It is not clear whether this would necessarily create a level playing field to the extent that special regimes are justified to compensate undue competitive disadvantages. The results from the CORTAX study for the 'mandatory for all' option presented in Table 7 indicate that in the aggregate domestic

69 To keep the structure of the assessment of various option dimensions consistent throughout the report the impact analysis in this section is divided into fairness impacts and economic impacts, even though the separation is not always clear-cut.

70 According to a survey conducted in 2015, only 4% of European SMEs had invested abroad at that time (European Commission (2015c)). Similarly, Navaretti et al. (2011) find a clear positive correlation between firm size and propensity to invest abroad in seven EU Member States (AT, FR, DE, HU, IT, ES, UK). Notably, the share of firms with foreign affiliates is several times larger for large firms than for SMEs.

71 See VVW (2015) and ZEW (2015).

firms (which may be small or not) do not benefit uniformly from the application of the CCCTB.

Overall, option 2d to make the CCCTB mandatory for all firms appears disproportionate to the extent that it would unnecessarily oblige these small and micro corporations to apply the CCCTB. Proportionality is also an important aspect of the EU Better regulation agenda and in particular its programme for regulatory fitness (REFIT), according to which legislation should avoid any unnecessary burden. In line with this approach, the intention is thus not to place, in the absence of any real benefits, a burden on smallersized companies of limited finances, which may not have the intention of expanding abroad. While this would come at the administrative cost of maintaining two corporate tax systems in parallel, it would also allow national corporate tax systems to stay more flexible and respond to domestic circumstances.

There are in principle three main criteria that could be used to select firms into the mandatory set: (i) a sectorial approach, (ii) an approach targeting multinational entities via a definition of cross-border groups and (iii) a size approach.

Sectorial approach

One could argue that some sectors, such as the financial sector, would be more suitable candidates than other sectors to the application of a CCCTB, notably because the farreaching harmonisation in regulation and supervision makes taxation one of the few

discriminating elements between companies of different Member States. 72 However, the

sectorial approach is not retained here as the problems identified in Section 2 are common to all sectors, albeit to possibly varying degrees, and as it is difficult to apprehend how an adequate and efficient solution to those problems can be achieved by applying a sectorial approach.

Cross-border criterion

Firms that currently benefit from cross-border tax planning have by definition a crossborder structure. This is therefore a natural requirement for the inclusion into the mandatory set. It may be considered as the 'minimum criterion', leading to the widest mandatory scope that is justifiable. However, mandating firms with cross-border operations into the CCCTB while domestic firms (even of a comparable size) are given the possibility, but are not obliged, to opt in, could be challenged on discrimination grounds. In addition, if not complemented by further criteria a cross-border criterion would capture about 4-5% of SMEs that are active cross-border (Table 8 below). On this basis, it is not suggested to focus on a cross-border criterion alone.

Size criterion

There is a clear correlation between size and propensity to operate in a cross-border structure (Table 8 below). Therefore, applying a size criterion might be a good alternative way for capturing those – essentially cross-border – businesses which have higher possibilities of engaging in tax avoidance practices. Furthermore, relying on a size criterion would better fit the necessity to avoid discrimination since it would not make

72 See e.g. Bénassy-Quéré, Trannoy and Wolff (2014).

any difference between a member of a multinational group and a member of a domestic group that, even just potentially, want to grow internationally or do business through permanent establishments. Finally, a size criterion would be consistent with the approach followed in the recently agreed amendment to the Directive on administrative cooperation to implement the country-by-country reporting. The reporting requirement will apply to groups with total consolidated revenue of at least EUR 750 million.

Different size thresholds could be envisaged above which the CCCTB would be mandatory. In that respect, the following elements serve as guiding principles.

First, as explained above, the threshold should aim at the right balance between the risk of tax avoiders falling below the CCCTB threshold and the risk of imposing the CCCTB to companies that do not engage in tax avoidance and would get little or no benefit from lessened compliance costs as they do not operate cross-border (i.e. threshold set too

low). 73

The available evidence on the link between a firm's size and its likelihood to engage in tax planning would point, if anything, to a rather high threshold. It is difficult to establish a clear direction for this link. The empirical literature finds evidence for both positive and negative relationships, pointing to a possible non-linear relationship. A recent meta-study by Belz et al. (2016) finds the overall effect to be rather positive. However, they also point to a changing picture based on studies that use more recent samples. Moreover, studies focussing on samples with larger firms show a significantly lower consensus estimate, indicating that these firms might indeed achieve lower effective tax rates. Data for the US show that average implicit tax rates (i.e. the tax payment divided by the taxable profit) increase with increasing firm size, except for the 5% largest firms. Examining this upper 5 percentile more closely shows that there is no significant trend in one or the other direction for the 95-99 percentile but that effective tax rates are significantly lower and decreasing in size for the 99-100 percentile (Bao and Romeo, 2013).

Analyses of the structure of tax compliance costs of companies suggest that spending on tax planning increases with firm size which could be interpreted as economies of scale in tax avoidance techniques. Eichfelder and Vaillancourt (2014) summarise the tax compliance cost literature of the last three decades and conclude that tax planning costs seem to be relatively unimportant for micro and small enterprises. The results could be interpreted in the sense that the fraction of planning costs increases with business size. This evidence has to be used cautiously due to the many weaknesses of the methods to estimate compliance costs and the exact definition of tax planning costs. Data provided by Slemrod and Venkatesh (2002) show that the share of tax planning costs in total compliance costs increases with firm size measured by the value of assets from 4% for companies with assets smaller than USD 5 million to 15% for companies with an asset size of more USD 1 billion.

73 In the OECD/G20 BEPS Report on Action 13, the following elements were put forward: the general

filing requirement for MNE groups with annual consolidated group turnover of more than EUR 750 million is believed to "exclude approximately 85 to 90 percent of MNE groups from the requirement to file the country-by-country report, but that the country-by-country report will nevertheless be filed by MNE groups controlling approximately 90 percent of corporate revenues. The prescribed exemption threshold therefore represents an appropriate balancing of reporting burden and benefit to tax administrations." (OECD, 2015b)

Second, by setting a threshold, a trade-off might emerge for some companies that may want to scale down or refrain from growing in order to remain outside the scope of the CCCTB. Such an effect is likely to be more acute if the threshold is low. The direction of the distortion would be that some firms above, but close to the frontier would stay

smaller than they would choose to be otherwise. 74 Unless at the outset firms are already

larger than optimal, this would imply an efficiency loss. The lower the threshold, the larger is the number of firms facing such a trade-off. A similar issue concerns the level playing field between companies below and above the threshold. Due to the possibility to opt in, firms below the threshold may be able to benefit from an advantage compared to competitors above the threshold. This concern is less pronounced for higher thresholds simply because there will be fewer instances of direct competitors being below and above the threshold.

Third, a very high threshold may give rise to concerns of creating a beneficial tax regime for the most mobile segment of the tax base, which would in turn harm taxpayer morale. In principle, Member States would have incentives to make the CCCTB regime attractive to attract mobile base. There are two reasons why this concern is of limited relevance. The notion of mobility will change under the CCCTB as shifting tax base requires the reallocation of factors. Furthermore, the possibility for companies to opt in implies that a country that lowers the CCCTB tax rate would risk a larger deterioration of revenues as more and more companies would opt in.

Table 8 gives an overview of the estimated scope of the CCCTB (in terms of number of companies and share of corporate revenues) for various thresholds.

Table 8: Estimated shares of groups, turnover and domestic groups for different size thresholds

Share of groups active Consolidated Share of groups, compared Corresponding share of only domestically

turnover to total number of groups unconsolidated turnover compared to total number

of groups in this bracket 75

<= EUR 50 million 96.1% 19.9% 95.2%

> EUR 50 million 3.9% 81.1% 51.0%

> EUR 500 million 1.9% 68.6% 24.5%

> EUR 750 million 1.6% 64.2% 19.2%

Source: ORBIS and ORBIS Historical Ownership (December 2014)

It is clear that corporate groups with consolidated turnover up to EUR 50 million, which corresponds roughly to SMEs, are overwhelmingly present in a single Member State only. Therefore, capturing the small share of SME groups active in more than one Member State would come at the expense of imposing a change to the CCCTB on a very large number of domestic firms. This would clearly not be a targeted measure. Moreover, even within the large groups with consolidated turnover of more than EUR 50 million,

74 Hasegawa et al (2013) find evidence for such effects based on experience with corporate transparency requirements in Japan.

75 This ratio has been computed for groups that have their global ultimate owner (GUO) in the EU. In

other words, groups active in the EU but with GUO outside the EU are not reflected in this ratio. This ratio therefore gives an upper estimate of the share of purely domestic groups.

slightly more than half of the large groups have a purely domestic structure. The share of domestic firms becomes significantly smaller only for considerably larger thresholds. Overall, the thresholds of EUR 500 million and EUR 750 million seem to produce fairly comparable results, capturing respectively 68.6% and 64.2% of turnover of all groups. They imply that a fraction of 19.2% and 24.5% of groups under mandatory application would be active only domestically.

5.2.2. Economic impacts

Results for the economic impacts using the CORTAX study have been obtained for two different assumptions on the set of firms that apply the CCCTB, namely either only multinational entities or all firms. As the results summarised in Table 4 and Table 5 show, the overall impact on key economic variables is very similar for the two options. However, the CORTAX model is not built to capture in a meaningful way the opt-in decision of a firm. The assumption that all multinationals opt into the CCCTB, whereas

domestic firms prefer to stay out is consistent with the other assumptions in the model, 76

but in reality a number of elements influence the opt-in decision.

In principle, one would expect economic impacts to be maximised if firms have the largest possible flexibility to choose the CCCTB. They would then self-select depending on whether the CCCTB or the respective national system better fits their needs, even though this would also entail a certain burden due to the required cost-benefit analysis preceding such a decision.

Impact on administrative burden

The main impacts on the compliance burden for companies have been discussed in Section 5.1. In principle it is expected that the CCCTB reduces the compliance burden for companies, at least for those that are active cross-border or wish to expand crossborder. There may be cases in which a company finds the respective national system easier to deal with. If companies have the possibility to opt into the CCCTB, they would factor in the compliance burden in their opt-in decision. In this respect a wider optional application would be better to reduce compliance costs. On the other hand firms would have to conduct a cost-benefit analysis before they decide. Since such cost-benefit analysis is a one-off cost, it is overall more beneficial from a compliance cost perspective to leave companies a choice.

Tax administrations, however, would benefit the most if the CCCTB is made mandatory for all firms, even though they would also incur one-off costs for switching to the new system. In terms of recurring costs, the burden for national administrations may go up slightly if the CCCTB is not mandatory for all firms due to the required maintenance of two parallel systems. In this case, they could still benefit from reduced case numbers due to the one-stop shop approach by which multinational companies deal with the tax administration of only one Member State.

76 This is why in the 2011 impact assessment the 'optional for all' option was translated into the assumption that all multinational entities would opt into the CCCTB.

5.2.3. Stakeholder views

Stakeholders were asked whether they support making the CCCTB obligatory for all EU groups. Roughly one-third of the respondents are in favour and the same fraction is against. Another 13% express a neutral stance while 15% opted for 'other'. Among companies, slightly more than half of SMEs support a mandatory application for all EU groups, whereas only 20% of the large companies are in favour. The absolute number of respondents representing respectively large companies and SMEs is relatively small though and the results should be interpreted cautiously. Comments given along with the replies suggest a wide range of nuances within each of the reply categories. Some consider it more appropriate to apply cross-border or turnover criteria and/or to exclude SMEs, and/or believe that a mandatory application should only be considered after an initial optional phase. The range of views is particularly wide for the opponents. Some prefer the CCCTB to be mandatory for all firms to ensure a level playing field. Some suggest size thresholds or an opt-out possibility. Others are in principle against the CCCTB.

5.2.4. Scope preferred option

Table 9 shows a summary of the performance of the two main scope definitions for the CCCTB against the baseline. Column (1) summarises the impacts of a mandatory application for all firms. Column (2) shows the impacts for the case of a limited mandatory application. Evaluated on their merits in reaching the objectives, both scope options improve the situation when compared to the baseline scenario. The option 'compulsory for all firms' is expected to perform slightly better in reducing tax planning opportunities and has the advantage to eliminate all national corporate tax systems which reduces costs for tax administrations in comparison to a limited mandatory application. Otherwise, the two options are expected to be similarly effective in stimulating growth and investment. However, the advantage of a full compulsory application in reducing tax planning opportunities is small if compared to a mandatory scope definition that captures the most relevant companies engaged in cross-border tax planning. At the same time, a fully compulsory approach would also force companies into the CCCTB system that have no tax planning opportunities and generally fewer benefits to reap from the CCCTB. This is not a proportionate approach to achieve the objectives. Instead, granting the possibility to apply the CCCTB to such companies, which are often active only domestically and tend to be smaller, creates a more level playing field between them and multinationals. Thus 'compulsory for all' is rejected.

It is proposed to make the CCCTB compulsory only for a subset of firms (option 2b), based on their size. A size criterion proves to be a good proxy for capturing, in a nondiscriminatory manner, companies that are likely to engage in tax avoidance practices. Defining the actual threshold implies a trade-off between the risk of not capturing tax avoiders and the risk of targeting companies that do not ordinarily engage in cross-border activities and would therefore not present a substantial tax avoidance risk. In addition, this second category of companies should be expected to operate business structures that would derive only little or no benefit from lessened compliance costs, given that they do not operate cross-border. It seems at the very least appropriate to exclude SMEs from the mandatory application as they are by and large not active internationally, hence unlikely to engage in tax avoidance. The link between size and likelihood to engage in tax planning being more robust for the very large firms, and taking into account the risk of adverse threshold effects (disincentives to grow), would point to a rather high threshold. Moreover, domestic firms do not seem as a whole to benefit from the CCCTB or from staying out. To account for their different needs and to ensure a more level playing field, it may be important to not oblige them to apply the system. This, too, points to a rather high threshold, considering the shares of purely domestic groups captured by the various thresholds displayed in Table 8.

Limiting the compulsory application to groups with a consolidated turnover above EUR 750 million would serve the purpose of capturing the vast majority (ca. 64%) of turnover generated by groups while limiting the risk of including purely domestic groups. Furthermore, such a threshold would be coherent with the approach taken in other EU initiatives to counter tax avoidance.

Table 9: Assessment of impacts of scope options

(1) (2)

Options Compulsory Compulsory for all firms application for a defined set of firms

Enhancing the Fairness of the Tax System

Reduce cross-border tax planning opportunities ++ +

More level playing field for domestic and multinational

companies + ++

Companies pay a fair share of the tax burden + +

Enhance general tax payer morale + +

Stimulating growth and investment

Simplify within the EU the currently highly complex

international system of corporate taxation ++ ++

Eliminate double taxation risks within the EU and remove still

existing discriminations and restrictions + +

Approach to profit taxation that does not distort investment

and financing decisions 0 0

More incentives to invest in the EU + +

Reduction in administrative burden for companies and

administrations + +

Source: European Commission

Note: The evaluation is based on a scale of five steps from very negative (- -) to very positive (++).

"0" indicates no change (i.e. neutrality).

Importantly, the assessment should be contrasted with the proportionality of each option. A 'compulsory for all' approach would put an unnecessary burden on some firms, in particular small and micro corporations. Those companies would not necessarily be able to benefit from reduced recurrent compliance costs and may no longer have access to specific tax regimes. This is disproportionate to the extent that including those companies would not much advance any of the two general objectives.

5.2.5. Independence of the preferred scope option with other option dimensions.

The choice for the mandatory scope does not change with respect to the preferred debt bias and R&D options. In relation to the debt bias, this relies on the AGI being the

preferred option, as developed below. 77 The level of generosity of the R&D options has

no critical implications for the scope question either. The more generous and the larger the set of firms that would opt in, the more limited the risk of not capturing all tax avoiders. However, it is not obvious how to translate this effect into an exact amount for the threshold.

5.3. Addressing the debt bias

This section examines how to address the debt bias in the CCCTB with the most effective and efficient option vis-à-vis the objectives. The available options are:

• 'No further action', which is equivalent to maintaining the situation as foreseen in the 2011 CCCTB proposal but aligned with the requirements by the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive (option 3a),

• the non-deductibility of interest payments (option 3b), • the allowance for corporate equity (option 3c), • the allowance for growth and investment (option 3d), and • the allowance for corporate capital (option 3e).

The cost of capital allowance (option 3f) has been discarded in Section 4.3. In line with the intervention logic, this section starts out with presenting the economic impacts, which are more relevant for the options for the debt bias. The same sequence is applied in the following section on R&D tax incentives.

5.3.1. Economic impacts

Impact on the financing decisions of firms

Current tax systems in the Member States usually provide a significant tax advantage to debt (see also Section 2.2.1). They indeed favour debt-financed investments by allowing a deduction of interest paid from the tax base, whereas there is no equivalent deduction for the cost of equity.

For the analysis of the economic impacts of this differential treatment, it is necessary to adopt an indicator that expresses the financing costs of a company for different sources of financing. The indicator used here is the cost of capital (this concept is explained in annex X). In most tax systems, the cost of capital is lower for debt-financed investment due to the favourable tax treatment of debt. A profit-maximizing company will exploit this difference and use more of the (cheaper) debt financing. Ideally, the cost of capital for debt and equity should be equal. In this case the tax system would be neutral with regard to financing decision (i.e. debt and equity face the same tax wedge).

77 If instead the preferred choice had been disallowing interest deductibility, which is a disadvantage

compared to national systems, this could have changed the considerations for the set of firms under mandatory application.

ZEW (2016a) analyses the impact of various tax reforms to address the debt bias on the

cost of capital. 78 The reforms simulate revenue neutrality to avoid that the results are driven by changes in revenue levels. Table 10 presents the results of the study. 79 Column

(1) shows the required cost of capital in the current tax systems assuming a real return on a safe alternative investment of 5%.

Table 10: Effect of revenue-neutral debt-bias reforms on the cost of capital (EU average)

Source of financing / (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Reform Current tax No interest ACE AGI ACC

(Cost of capital in %) systems deductibility

Retained Earnings 6.7 6.5 4.5 4.5 4.5

New Equity 6.8 6.6 4.6 4.6 4.6

Debt 4.7 6.5 4.5 4.5 4.5

Mean 6.0 6.5 4.5 4.5 4.5

Debt Bias* 2.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1

Source: ZEW (2016a).

Note: *Debt Bias: This is computed as the cost of capital for new equity minus the cost of capital for debt. Revenue neutrality is achieved by adjusting the statutory CIT rate to achieve the same effective average tax rate. For ACE, AGI and ACC, the defined interest rate assumed is 7.1%, corresponding to the long-term nominal interest rate on a risk-free bond. The analysis is not qualitatively affected by the assumed rate (ZEW, 2016b).

The analysis shows that reform options to address the debt bias largely eliminate taxinduced financing distortions by equalizing the cost of capital of debt-financed investments and equity-financed investments.

Implementing the non-deductibility of interest increases the cost of capital for debt up to the level for equity. Non-deductibility of interest leads to a broader tax base, which allows reducing the CIT rate to achieve revenue neutrality. Due to this lower tax rate, the cost of capital decreases slightly also for equity. Overall, the reform leads to an increase in the mean cost of capital from 6.0 to 6.5%, despite the decrease in the CIT rate.

The allowance for corporate equity (ACE, option 3c), allowance for growth and investment (AGI, option 3d) and the allowance for corporate capital (ACC, option 3e) show identical results. They differ only with respect to their tax treatment of debt, with the ACC providing a defined deduction whereas ACE and AGI generally allow for the

deductibility of actual interest paid. 80 This design difference does not matter here since the assumed defined rate is identical to the nominal market interest rate. 81 All reforms

reduce the tax base and thus require an increase in the CIT rate to keep revenue

neutrality. 82 Despite the increase in the tax rate to guarantee revenue neutrality, the cost

78 Details on the concept and the underlying model are available in annexes IV and XII.

79 It should be noted that our model does not distinguish between the ACE and the AGI, which have here the same macroeconomic effects.

80 The model can simulate neither the effects of specific corrections done under the AGI nor its

incremental features. Hence it cannot differentiate between the ACE and the AGI. 81 Irrespective of the defined rate, the ACC always achieves financing neutrality. In contrast, full

financing neutrality for the ACE and the AGI is achieved only if the rate equals the market interest rate.

82 Note, however, that for the ACC the impact on the base depends on the level of the defined rate chosen. For sufficiently low rates, the tax base may be broader than in the status quo.

of capital for equity decreases considerably. 83 Overall, the cost of capital decreases by

25%, from 6.0% to 4.5%. The reason for this result is that the cost of capital measures the cost of an investment at the margin, i.e. the tax burden on the last euro invested. The three reforms reduce this marginal burden thereby fostering investment. In contrast, the tax burden on the economic rent, i.e. the profit above the normal market return is taxed higher. From an economic point of view this type of taxation is efficiency enhancing since it leads to fewer distortions in the investment decision of companies.

In the central scenario, the CCCTB (option 1b) is implemented without specific provisions to address the debt bias but there would still be certain limitations on interest deductibility (as following the implementation of the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive, interest deductibility limitations will be part of the CCCTB). Such limitation rules have already been discussed in Council after the 2011 proposal. They would deny interest deductibility partially either with respect to debt that leads to 'thin capitalisation' (meaning an insufficient equity base relative to debt) or with respect to interest expenses that exceed a certain percentage of gross earnings. These rules would overall imply a

strengthening of deductibility limitations currently applied in Member States. 84 They are,

however, not designed to achieve financing neutrality of the corporate tax system and they tackle tax-induced indebtedness only partially.

Based on the results on the impact on cost of capital, all reform options are expected to increase the share of equity in corporations. The introduction of an ACE in Belgium in 2006 and in Italy in 2011 offer the possibility to assess empirically their effect on

leverage. 85 For Belgium, a number of studies find a reduction in leverage of nonfinancial Belgian firms after the introduction of the ACE. 86 Schepens (2015) finds similar

effects for the financial sector. For Italy, Panteghini et al. (2012) find evidence of a significant decrease in the leverage of firms following the introduction of the ACE.

As no country has applied full non-deductibility of interest or an ACC, there is no empirical evidence on their effects. Some research found that partial limitations of

interest via anti-abuse rules have somewhat decreased the leverage of companies. 87

Finally, simulations with CORTAX indicate that all options would indeed reduce the leverage of firms, ranging from a decrease by 1.8% in the case of the ACE and AGI to 4.4% with the no interest deductibility (see Table 11).

Impacts on investment and growth

The macroeconomic impacts of the three potential reforms and the central scenario (in which the CCCTB is implemented without a debt-bias reform) are summarized in Table

83 Due to the deductibility of interest the tax base for a 'marginal investment' (see annex XII) is small.

Therefore changes in tax rates have little impact and changes in the tax base dominate. 84 As discussed in ZEW (2016b, chapter 6.1), 16 Member States apply interest deductibility limits to

intra-group debt only (of which 9 simply apply the arm's length principle without any specific rule), whereas the other 12 Member States apply specific limitations to both intra-group and third-party debt.

85 The ACE in Belgium has some resemblance with the traditional ACE as it is based on stock of equity and the anti-avoidance framework, although the way certain tax planning opportunities are addressed is considered as incomplete by some (e.g. Zangari, 2014). In contrast, the Italian system is closer to the AGI as it is based on incremental equity and has a relatively complete anti-avoidance framework.

86 See Princen (2012), aus dem Moore (2013), Panier et al. (2015) and Hebous and Ruf (2015).

87 See for example Büttner et al. (2012) and Blouin et al. (2014).

  • 11. 
    As before, the results have been obtained using CORTAX, which simulates all reforms in an ex-ante revenue-neutral way by adjusting the CIT rate. The macroeconomic effects of the ACE and the AGI are positive and superior to those of the no-action scenario, the ACC and the non-deductibility of interest. The table shows the case of a CCCTB applied to multinational entities only, but similar results are obtained under all

possible variations (CCTB or CCCTB, all firms or multinational entities only). 88 In all

these variations, the non-deductibility of interest leads to a negative effect on GDP, driven by depressed investment.

The CORTAX model does not incorporate the incremental feature of the AGI, i.e. the fact that it is only granted on equity increases. Sensitivity analyses presented in annex XIII suggest that the extent of the economic impacts depends on the exact calibration of the AGI (and the ACE), notably the choice of the rate.

The impact on investment has been assessed empirically for the Belgian ACE. 89 Aus dem

Moore (2014b) finds "highly significant and robust estimates that correspond to an increase in investment activity by small and medium-sized firms of about 3 percent in response to the ACE reform". Hebous and Ruf (2015) find no effect on production investment from multinational affiliates, which are the focus of their study. Zangari (2014) concludes that while the Belgian ACE has possibly benefitted investment by SMEs, multinationals seem to have used the ACE mostly as a tax planning device. He stresses the weaknesses of the anti-avoidance framework of the Belgian ACE as opposed to Italy's system, where the same effect has not been reported. In addition, the fact that the Belgian ACE at its introduction was granted on the already existing stock of a company's equity implied a windfall gain for companies, without any impact on investment decisions or their financing source.

88 The results are confirmed even if one allows companies in the model to relocate their activities in response to taxation (JRC, 2016).

89 As neither a full non-deductibility of interest nor an ACC have been applied in practice, no empirical

study exists. In addition, the Italian and the Cypriot ACE are too recent to offer long enough timeseries data to investigate their impact on investment.

Table 11: Economy-wide impacts of budget-neutral debt bias reforms under the CCCTB Multinational entities only – GDP-weighted EU-28 average

%-change unless stated (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) otherwise

(compared to no CCCTB – CCCTB CCCTB CCCTB CCCTB CCCTB

baseline scenario) central with no interest with ACE with AGI with ACC scenario deductibility

Cost of capital (change in

percentage points) -0.04 0.14 -0.32 -0.32 -0.14

Investment 0.57 -0.90 3.36 3.36 1.41

Share of debt-financed

investment 1.53% - 4 . 37 - 1.79 - 1.79 -4. 31

Wages 0.40 -0.02 1.26 1.26 0.71

Employment 0.19 -0.15 0.65 0.65 0.30

Welfare (%GDP) 0.07 0.13 0.18 0.18 0.16

GDP 0.16 -0.37 1.17 1.17 0.48

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016).

Note: All simulations are changes compared to the baseline scenario of no CCCTB

The CORTAX simulations do now allow capturing the incremental feature of the AGI. However, sensitivity analysis on the level of the allowance base suggest that the economic impacts of the AGI depend on its exact calibration.

Impacts on tax revenue

Revenue impacts are difficult to assess for non-deductibility of interest and the ACC since none of the systems have so far been implemented. For the non-deductibility of interest a back-of-the-envelope calculation, which does not take into account behavioural responses, suggests an increase in CIT collected of between 0.4% and 1% of GDP (see annex XII).

Regarding the revenue impact of the ACE, De Mooij (2012) finds a potential decrease in the tax base by 14.1% and in tax collection by 0.49% of GDP. Zangari (2014) finds that for the period 2009-2011, the revenue losses of the ACE represented about a third of CIT collected. He estimates that the revenue cost would be lower by 15% taking into account reductions in deductible interest as companies substitute debt for equity. The National Bank of Belgium (2008) puts this correction at about a third of the gross revenue loss in 2006. More details on these analyses are available in annex XII.

The CORTAX simulations allow evaluating the additional revenue impact of debt bias reforms compared to the CCCTB central scenario, i.e. the CCCTB without addressing the debt bias. The figures are subject to a number of caveats. Notably it should be kept in mind that CORTAX ensures budget-neutrality by adjusting the CIT rate and lump sum transfers. In terms of total tax revenues the additional impact from 'non-deductibility of interest payments' is positive in the order of EUR 13 billion (0.1% of GDP), due to a larger increase in CIT revenues partly compensated by a decrease in other tax revenues. The ACE/AGI reform is expected to decrease total tax revenue by EUR 19 billion (0.1% of GDP), due to a larger decrease in CIT revenues partly compensated by an increase in other tax revenues. With its design, the AGI is supposed to lead to lower revenue losses than the ACE and could be made fully revenue-neutral by introducing offsetting tax rate increases, without affecting the positive impact on financing neutrality. The ACC is almost neutral with a negative impact of EUR 1 billion, due to a decrease in CIT revenues largely offset by an increase in other taxes.

Impact on administrative burden

None of the options seem to imply important changes in administrative burden. They concern only one aspect of the computation of the tax base and are not per se more burdensome than e.g. the application of depreciation rules. The non-deductibility of interest is straightforward as is the application of a defined interest rate to equity.

The application of anti-avoidance rules may generate additional compliance and administrative costs for companies and tax administrations respectively. This is specifically the case for the AGI but, depending on their depth, also for the ACE and the ACC. These costs of course need to be balanced with the objectives of fairness. Compared to the no-action scenario and the non-deductibility of interest, the application of AGI, ACE and ACC could then lead to increased administrative burden.

5.3.2. Fairness impacts

The design of individual debt-bias reforms is crucial for the impacts on fairness. Not addressing the debt bias would leave opportunities for groups operating cross-border to shift profit via the debt instrument, at least under a common base.

Fully disallowing interest deductibility would suppress such opportunities and would therefore address the fairness aspects. The ACC would reduce tax planning opportunities via transfer price manipulations on interest rates as the deductible interest would not be based on the actual rate but on a defined one.

The ACE has been criticised because of the tax planning opportunities 90 it can

theoretically open in the form of cascading of the deductions on the same initial capital. Under the current system, interest paid is taxed at the level of the receiver, which is justified by the fact that the payment is tax deductible at the level of the payer. At the level of company groups, the reverse is true for dividends. Dividends paid are not taxed at the level of the receiver (via participation exemption in the EU), which finds its justification by the fact that they are not deductible at the level of the payer. The ACE changes this system by allowing a notional deduction for equity at the level of the payer (but does not change the exemption for dividends at the level of the receiver). This opens the following possibility to cascade the benefits of deductions: a parent borrows debt (D) from a bank and/or receives equity injections (E p ) from shareholders and re-injects the full amount of capital into a subsidiary as equity (E s = D+E p ). Under an ACE system without proper anti-avoidance rules, the parent company receives tax deductions in the form of ACE and deductible interest on its equity Ep and its debt D, respectively. The subsidiary receives a tax deduction in the form of an ACE on the same (transferred) capital.

90 For the Belgian ACE, Hebous and Ruf (2015) find indications for the use of such tax planning strategies.

Figure 8: Cascading of benefits under ACE

Shareholders Banks E p D

Div Parent Int p Profit

p = X p – ACE/AGI p -int

E s Div s

Profit s = X s – ACE/AGI s Subsidiary

Source: European Commission

To avoid such cascading, there is a need to make sure that the same euro of capital

invested in the group receives tax deductibility only once. 91 This is achieved with an

allowance for growth and investment (AGI). The embedded anti-avoidance measures ensure that the funds injected in a group benefit only once from a deductibility (via deductible actual interest or the allowance on equity). The system would remove the loopholes used for aggressive tax planning.

These specific rules to make the system robust to tax planning can include inter alia a stricter definition of the ACE/AGI base to exclude items that do not represent business needs or genuine investment, as well as participations and own shares, the limitation of the benefits of the ACE/AGI both in time (via an incremental system with a moving reference date) and amount (with a fixed limit), general anti-abuse rules (GAAR) and specific anti-abuse rules in terms of interest limitation rule; last but not least the AGI offers a correction mechanism at the level of either the parent or the subsidiary to avoid the cascading of the benefits.

5.3.3. Stakeholder views

In the stakeholders' consultation (see annex II), an overwhelming majority of respondents have voiced that the debt bias shall be addressed in the proposal. Among companies who responded more than 60% are in favour of addressing the debt bias, large companies and SMEs alike.

Most of the NGOs opt for the non-deductibility of interest method whereas from the

companies' perspective there is resounding support for the ACE/AGI 92 . Like the

companies, a strong majority of business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms expressed their preference for the ACE/AGI. A few respondents were in favour of the ACC/CoCA. Some respondents indicated that anti-avoidance measures are an important component of a possible ACE/AGI.

91 Zangari (2014) discusses the Belgian and Italian ACE systems and the role of anti-avoidance

provisions targeting intra-group transactions. 92 The AGI was not formally part of the public consultation as it is a special case of the ACE.

Several respondents mention the interest limitation rules foreseen in BEPS action 4 to indicate that interest limitation shall probably not go beyond those. Finally, many respondents emphasise the need for a solution to promote investment.

5.3.4. Debt bias preferred option.

In light of the above, deductibility for equity costs in the form of an allowance for growth and investment (AGI, option 3d) is the option that scores best in terms of economic outcomes while at the same time addressing the fairness aspects of the tax system.

Indeed, looking back at the objectives, both the non-deductibility of interest and the AGI would reduce tax planning opportunities, something the ACE would not do. When it comes to levelling the playing field for domestic and multinational companies, we have seen that the debt bias is particularly detrimental for SMEs, which constitute a large share of domestic companies. By entirely removing the debt bias, all options have the potential to help SMEs. However, the ACE and the ACC offer planning opportunities that would favour multinational entities over domestic companies.

The ACE, AGI and ACC may bring some complexity notably when it comes to their details. This is certainly true when compared to the non-deductibility of interest which is a simple, albeit radical, solution. However, a specific issue arises with the application of the full non-deductibility of interest in the financial sector. Applying the full nondeductibility of interest paid to the financial sector would represent a disproportionate financial cost for the sector, unless by symmetry the interest received would be exempted. This however would in turn mean that the larger part of traditional banking would be exempted from corporate taxation. Another practical question concerns the compatibility of non-deductibility of interest within the international landscape. In most countries interest is taxed based on residence whereas disallowing interest deductibility would imply moving to taxation at source.

In the panel of options, only the AGI – by ensuring that deductibility is granted only once

– offers a remedy without leading to double taxation. The non-deductibility of interest creates double taxation unless interest received is exempted at the level of the recipient.

In theory, all options should offer a satisfactory remedy to the distortions in the financing decisions. However, the same is not true when it comes to investment decisions and the attractiveness of the EU as the non-deductibility of interest would have adverse effects and the ACE would distort choices because of potential tax planning opportunities.

Taking no action, i.e. introducing the CCCTB without a debt bias solution, would imply that problems due to distorted financing incentives remain unaddressed, whereas profit shifting via debt would be mitigated to a certain degree through limitation rules in the CCCTB on interest deductibility.

In conclusion, the AGI addresses the debt bias and is expected to have a positive impact on the investment, even if implemented in a revenue-neutral way. The robust antiavoidance framework inherent to the AGI makes it the preferred debt bias option.

Table 12 summarises the impacts of the different debt bias options and assesses them against the central scenario for a CCCTB. This means that options are compared to a situation with a CCCTB which does not address the debt bias. The table therefore answers the questions whether a debt bias solution will improve the CCCTB vis-à-vis the central scenario. The analysis shows that granting no interest deductibility at all is attractive to reduce tax planning opportunities. At the same time this option clearly hampers investment due to its impact on capital costs. An allowance for equity features high on improving the economic environment, but scores lower when tax planning considerations are taken into account. The allowance for growth and investment (AGI) comes with stricter anti-avoidance rules and is only granted on incremental changes in the capital stock. It provides economic benefits while reducing the risks of tax planning. The allowance for the cost of capital (ACC) is similar to an ACE, but less favourable in economic terms.

Table 12: Assessment of impacts of debt-bias options

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Options No Interest ACE AGI ACC

deductibility

Enhancing the fairness of the tax system

Reduce cross-border tax planning opportunities + - + 0

More level playing field for domestic and

multinational companies + 0 + 0

Companies pay a fair share of the tax burden n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.

Enhance general tax payer morale n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.

Stimulating growth and investment

Simplify within the EU the currently highly complex international system of corporate + 0 0 0 taxation

Eliminate double taxation risks within the EU and remove still existing discriminations and - 0 + 0 restrictions

Approach to profit taxation that does not distort

investment and financing decisions - 0 + +

More incentives to invest in the EU -- ++ ++ +

Reduction in administrative burden for companies

and administrations 0 0 0 0

Source: European Commission

Note: The evaluation is based on a scale of five steps from very negative (- -) to very positive (++).

"0" indicates no change (i.e. neutrality).

5.3.5. Independence of the debt bias preferred option with other option dimensions

The conclusion on the preferred debt bias option does not depend on the preferred option for the scope or the R&D incentive. The results from the CORTAX and ZEW studies confirm that the ranking of debt bias options is stable, irrespective of the scope (and indeed independent also from consolidation). The specific design of the R&D incentive should not have implications for the choice on scope or debt bias either. The debt bias is a wider issue, changing the cost of capital for all investments, not only R&D investments.

5.4. Treatment of R&D expenses

This section reviews the two retained options for ensuring that the CCCTB provides sufficient incentives to invest in R&D. The available options are 'No further action' on R&D (option 4a), which is equivalent to immediate expensing of R&D in the 2011 CCCTB proposal, and granting a super allowance for R&D expenses (option 4b). The options of granting tax credits or granting tax incentives for income from intellectual property (option 4c) have been discarded in Section 4.4.

5.4.1. Economic impacts

Option 4a provides full and immediate deductibility for R&D expenses. 93 The majority

of national tax incentives provide currently larger than full immediate expensing (additional allowances amount to up to 200% in Latvia and Lithuania) or a tax credit for

qualifying R&D costs. 94 Annex XI provides an overview table of the systems currently

applied in Member States and selected third countries.

A systematic comparison of the generosity levels requires a measure which condenses different features of the tax system (rate, design of the incentive, etc.) into one indicator. Such an indicator of tax support to R&D is the '1-B-index' (see box 3). This index takes the value zero if the tax system does not provide any tax incentive on business R&D expenses beyond immediate expensing of all R&D expenses. It takes a positive value if the incentive is larger. It takes a negative value if the incentive is smaller.

Box. 3 The B-index and the 1-B-index

The B-index measures the minimum level of profit before tax that a representative company needs to earn to break even on one euro spent on R&D. The B-index summarises a large array of qualitative and quantitative information about R&D tax incentives and depreciation regimes for R&D assets as collected by the OECD. An alternative and more intuitive way is to look at the one minus B-index.

1-B-index = Tax subsidy (if positive) or tax burden (if negative).

The 1-B-index shows the influence of R&D tax incentives on the price of business R&D (user cost). For example, a value of 0.1 suggests that the price for a business to invest in R&D is 10% lower than it would have been in the absence of taxation, whereas a value of -.05 suggests that the user cost is 5% higher than it would have been in the absence of taxation. A value of 0 corresponds to the case of no taxation.

Source: OECD and Warda (2001).

Table 13 shows the computations of the 1-B index for all EU countries. The values are positive in 21 Member States, i.e. these Member States provide more tax support beyond full immediate expensing. They are negative in four Member States and the value is zero for three Member States. The weighted average of the tax subsidy rate for the EU stands at 0.12. This means that for every euro invested in business R&D in the EU, Member States give on average a subsidy of 12 cents.

93 As explained in Section 3.6.1., the exception is expenses for R&D buildings which cannot be immediately expensed, but these account for only 5% of total R&D expenditure.

94 These considerations may be affected in case a country requires capitalisation of some current R&D

costs. The effect of expensing or capitalisation of current R&D costs was considered in preparation for the 2011 proposal and the results of the simulation reveal no considerable impact (ZEW, 2008).

Option 4a offers immediate expensing for all R&D costs except for the estimated 5% related to buildings and land. This would translate into a tax burden on R&D of -0.01 and not maintain the current generosity level of the tax treatment of R&D expenses.

Table 13: T ax subsidy rates as measured by the '1-B-index' in EU Member States.

Country B-index 1-B-index Country B-index 1-B-index

Germany 1.02 -0.02 Slovak Republic 0.89 0.11

Finland 1.01 -0.01 Austria 0.88 0.12

Denmark 1.01 -0.01 Netherlands 0.84 0.16

Luxembourg 1.01 -0.01 Slovenia 0.81 0.19

Cyprus 1.00 0.00 Czech Republic 0.77 0.23

Bulgaria 1.00 0.00 Croatia 0.74 0.26

Estonia 1.00 0.00 France 0.74 0.26

Poland 0.98 0.02 Hungary 0.72 0.28

Italy 0.96 0.04 Ireland 0.71 0.29

Sweden 0.95 0.05 Latvia 0.69 0.31

Romania 0.92 0.08 Lithuania 0.68 0.32

Greece 0.91 0.09 Portugal 0.64 0.36

United Kingdom 0.90 0.10 Spain 0.63 0.37

Belgium 0.89 0.11 Malta 0.51 0.49

EU-28 – EU-28 –

simple average 0.85 0.15 GDP-weighted average 0.88 0.12

Source: OECD calculations, where available. Joint Research Centre and DG Taxation and Customs Union

Note: Calculations for missing EU countries and for Poland following the regime change in 2016.

Impact on R&D investment

The vast majority of empirical research concludes that expense-based R&D tax

incentives lead to additional R&D investment. 95 The estimates of the size of this effect

are widely diverging, partly due to differences in methodologies and countries covered by the studies. Recent studies conclude that the tax elasticity (the proportional change in R&D spending due to a 1% decrease in the tax burden) is positive and close to, but less

than one. 96

To reflect these results in a plausible but conservative manner, an elasticity of 0.8 is

assumed in the calculations presented in table 14. 97 An elasticity of 0.8 means that a 10%

reduction in the price of business R&D results in an 8% increase in business R&D. In line with the result above that Option 4a would lead to a deterioration in incentives, the analysis finds an 18% reduction in R&D spending compared to the baseline (existing

95 See the study by CPB (2014) for a recent survey of the literature.

96 See for example CPB (2014), Becker (2015) and Koehler et al. (2012). The effects, may, however be

underestimated, as some research suggests that R&D tax incentives may assessed to be less effective than they really are if studies do not take into account the endogenous determination of tax policies, i.e. the fact that tax reforms are often introduced to offset economic downturns (Chang, 2014).

97 Alternative calculations were also performed using a plausible range of literature-backed elasticities

(from 0.5 to 1.2). Minimum and maximum bounds suggested by these alternative elasticities are also presented.

national schemes). An additional allowance (option 4b) of 33% is required to achieve the same level of tax subsidy as in current national tax schemes.

Table 14: Reform scenarios and their possible impact on R&D investment

Pre-reform: B-index:

EU-28 GDP-weighted average 0.88 Expected % change in R&D expenditures:

Post-reform: Elasticity 1.2 Elasticity 1.0 Elasticity 0.8 Elasticity 0.5

Option 4a, full expensing 1.01 -0.27 -0.22 -0.18 -0.11

Option 4b, full expensing, 33% bonus

allowance 0.88 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Option 4b, full expensing, 100% bonus

allowance 0.69 0.25 0.21 0.17 0.10

Option 4b, full expensing, 200% bonus

allowance 0.38 0.78 0.65 0.52 0.32

Source: Joint Research Centre and DG Taxation and Customs Union. European Commission.

Note: R&D buildings are depreciated under all options. Inclusion of own-calculated B-indices leads to a lower average tax subsidy in the EU than the one calculated based on the available OECD indices as the GDP- weighted average B-index drops from 0.88 to 0.86. Under the B-index of 0.86, the full expensing has worse consequences on R&D, as the drop in R&D is -23% (from -18% with the full set of 28 B-indexes). An allowance of 37% is needed to achieve pre-reform levels (up from 33%).

An additional allowance of 100% (on top of full expensing) would significantly improve existing incentives to engage in R&D, with an expected increase of about 17% in business R&D investment compared to the status quo. Meeting the Europe 2020 target of 3% of GDP devoted to R&D would require an even bolder allowance. If 2% of GDP were to come from the private sector, business R&D investment would need to increase

by 54% from current levels. 98 An additional allowance of 200% could result in an

increase in business R&D by 52%, approximately meeting the Europe 2020 target.

However, the effectiveness of an additional allowance of a given level will vary with the applicable CIT rate. The higher the tax rate the larger the benefit for the company investing in R&D and thus the stronger the incentive to invest. Under the CCCTB the relevant rate would depend on a weighted average of tax rates after formula apportionment. To the extent that Member States change CIT rates after introduction of the CCCTB this could change the generosity level of the allowance.

Impact on tax revenue

In terms of foregone tax revenues, granting an additional allowance of 33% should have an overall neutral impact on CIT revenues as it corresponds to the R&D tax incentives

already offered in EU Member States. 99 Estimates of the likely changes in CIT revenues

under the two options for different rates of the allowance, as presented in annex XII, vary from 5% for an additional allowance of 100% to 15% for an allowance of 200%. These estimates are broadly in line with OECD (2015c).

Neither of these estimates takes into account revenue gains from the reversal of all patent boxes currently applied in the EU. Griffith et al. (2014) simulate the revenue impacts of

98 R&D business expenses stood at 1.3% of GDP in 2014 and thus the shortfall in the EU amounts to

0.7% of GDP (Eurostat data). 99 The effect will depend on the tax rates Member States choose after the introduction of a CCCTB.

introducing patent boxes in four countries. They find that tax revenues from new patents are less than half of their pre-reform levels in the four countries concerned. The impact from the removal of patent box regimes would be the same for both options.

Impact on different types of companies and possible targeting of R&D incentives

A conclusion from the economic literature is that tax incentives should not be linked to the size of a company but rather to the desirable outcome such as more research and

innovation investment. 100

The effects of R&D tax incentives vary across firm types, notably size. In general, there is no undisputed conclusion whether SMEs respond more strongly to R&D tax incentives than large companies. Recent evidence however suggests that knowledge spillovers from large firms exceed those from small firms (Bloom et al, 2013). Targeting R&D tax incentives to firm size needs to consider both, the degree of responsiveness and the level of spillovers. There is nevertheless evidence that size may not be the best selection criterion as the impact of tax incentives on R&D spending for start-up firms can exceed the average impact. Therefore, targeting young companies can be considered a better

practice than targeting SMEs. 101

If the CCCTB is more generous than national tax incentives schemes, it could be seen as favouring incumbent firms. This is because more generous R&D tax incentives can be associated with a more concentrated growth distribution in R&D intensive sectors, which may favour incumbent firms (Bravo-Biosca et al., 2013). Young companies can challenge incumbent businesses and generate proportionally more jobs (Criscuolo et al., 2014). The EU has currently fewer young leading innovative companies than the US in fast moving sectors (Cincera and Veugelers, 2013). Tax incentives can hence be designed to support young companies directly with relatively more generous provisions (as currently applied in France, Belgium, the Netherlands and Portugal), by including options to carry forward the R&D expenditure (as in most national schemes) and/or to get a cash refund (as in seven EU countries). Such features offer young firms more flexibility and reduce the uncertainty associated with investment decisions.

Impact on EU competitiveness

Based on the conclusion that option 4a weakens current incentives for businesses to invest in R&D and given that the EU underinvests in private R&D compared to other innovation leaders such as US, Japan and South Korea (which all apply R&D tax incentives), option 4a could further deteriorate the competitive position of EU businesses and could also lead to delocalisation of R&D efforts of EU businesses from the EU to other countries.

100 This seems to be the focus as well in national tax systems. A 2015 study on SME taxation concludes that SME tax incentives are not as frequently implemented as R&D tax incentives. Mostly, reduced tax rates are employed to support SMEs on which available evidence suggests that such SME reduced rates may prevent companies from growing (IMF, 2016). Most SME tax incentives seem to benefit only micro and small enterprises, while medium-sized corporations basically benefit only from R&D tax incentives (see also table 37 in annex XI). Reductions in the effective tax burden due to R&D tax incentives for large corporations comes mostly from reductions applicable to the tax base, i.e. enhanced allowances (VVA and ZEW, 2015).

101 See the discussion and evidence provided in CPB (2014), OECD (2016) and IMF (2016).

The likely impact of the tax treatment of R&D expenses on GDP growth is difficult to estimate. The IMF (2016) expects a long-term increase in GDP of about 5% following an increase in business R&D by 38% based on the literature estimates of the elasticity of output with respect to changes in business R&D. Extrapolating from this, an allowance of 100% and 200% may increase GDP by roughly 2% and 7%, respectively. However,

linear extrapolations should be treated with caution. 102

Impact on administrative burden

As explained above, introducing the CCCTB is expected to reduce administrative burden in relation to R&D tax incentives, which currently vary considerably across the EU (annex XI). This reduction in administrative burden is expected to be the same for options 4a and 4b.

5.4.2. Fairness impacts

Stimulating R&D activities should also contribute to the objective of enhancing fairness. 13 EU countries currently offer tax reductions on the income earned from exploiting intellectual property. Such patent boxes have been introduced in recent years with the declared objective of boosting R&D, high-tech jobs and competitiveness. However, patent boxes have been criticized from the outset. Research shows that they do not stimulate R&D and may rather be used as a profit-shifting instrument, leading to high revenue losses. Section 4.4 discusses this more and Table 1 in Section 2.1 illustrates the large tax saving potential by exploiting patent boxes. Patent boxes reward successful innovations which already profit from an intellectual property protection. They could thus make research efforts that are not patentable, with potentially higher social

spillovers, less attractive. Furthermore, the use of intellectual rights is sector specific. 103

Overall, both options 4a and 4b would increase fairness by reducing IP-related profit shifting and improving the level playing field between those research efforts which benefit from IP-protection and those which do not.

5.4.3. Stakeholder views

A majority of respondents (55%) are in favour of making the CCCTB more favourable for R&D than in the 2011 CCCTB proposal, while 18% are against. Those in favour are companies – in fact all large companies and 80% of SMEs who responded - while most of the NGOs and private individuals are against a more favourable regime.

102 The variance observed in quantitative literature on the returns to R&D (e.g. Hall et al., 1999) argues

against crude linear extrapolations. In fact literature on the statistical distribution of highly valuable

inventions (e.g. Scherer and Harhoff, 2000; Silverberg and Verspagen, 2007) suggests that they have

no mean and no variance and therefore attempts to forecast the aggregate outcome of R&D with

precision need to be treated with caution.

103 Hall et al. (2013) find that in the UK even among firms that conduct R&D, only 4% patent. Findings

are similar for the US as 5.5% of US manufacturing firms own a patent (Balasubramanian and

Sivadasan, 2011). Sectors such as computers, electronics, machinery, chemical and pharmaceuticals

seem to have the highest patenting activities (Squicciarini and Dernis 2013). The empirical evidence

suggests that for many sectors patents seem an ineffective way to appropriate returns and secrecy and

lead times are used extensively (Arundel, 2001; Hanel, 2008; Hall et al., 2014).

Around half of the respondents who are against making the framework more favourable refer to concerns about harmful tax competition induced by tax schemes based on income from intellectual property. Many respondents highlight that any scheme under the CCCTB should be based on actual R&D costs. Other responses in this group suggest a preference for other means to stimulate R&D.

The suggestions of respondents who are in favour of making the framework more favourable mostly concentrate on super deductions.

Across the various groups of respondents, some believe that Member States should be allowed to retain their flexibility in granting R&D tax credits or super deductions in parallel to the CCCTB.

5.4.4. Preferred R&D option

Given its impact on R&D investment and positive spillovers for the whole society, option 4b, i.e. granting an additional allowance, is preferable to maintaining the 2011 CCCTB proposal on R&D (option 4a). An additional allowance between 33% and 100% would be preferable to maintain or further encourage R&D investment in the EU at a reasonable cost. To stimulate growth of innovative firms and ensure fairness, a more generous provision could be proposed to young innovative companies that would opt into the CCCTB. An alignment of definitions and eligible costs with EU state aid rules would ensure coherence with other EU policies.

Table 15 summarizes the impacts of the two options. Column (1) shows the central scenario for the CCCTB which by definition is neutral (option 4a). Column (2) shows the impacts in comparison to this central scenario of an additional allowance (4b).

Table 15: Assessment of impacts of R&D options

Options (Option 4a) (Option 4b)

2011 R&D Additional treatment in R&D

CCCTB allowance

Enhancing the fairness of the tax system

Reduce cross-border tax planning opportunities 0 0

More level playing field for domestic and multinational companies 0 0

Companies pay a fair share of the tax burden n/a n/a

Enhance general taxpayer morale n/a n/a

Stimulating growth and investment

Simplify within the EU the currently highly complex international 0 0 system of corporate taxation

Eliminate double taxation risks within the EU and remove still existing 0 0 discriminations and restrictions

Approach to profit taxation that does not distort investment and n/a n/a financing decisions

More incentives to invest in the EU (impact on R&D) 0 ++

Reduction in administrative burden for companies and administrations 0 0

Source: European Commission

Note: The evaluation is based on a scale of five steps from very negative (- -) to very positive (++).

"0" indicates no change (i.e. neutrality).

5.4.5. Independence of the R&D preferred option with other option dimensions

The preferred choice for the treatment of R&D expenses does not have important dependencies with the preferred option for the scope or the debt bias. This is due to the possibility to opt in and the objective to include R&D tax incentives that are at least as generous as what Member States currently apply. However, it is possible that in some cases a company will have more incentives to invest in R&D under the national system, but falls under the mandatory scope. This would be an argument for keeping the threshold for the mandatory application rather high to reduce the possibility for such cases. The considerations between the principal choices for the R&D incentive (additional allowance, tax credit etc.) do not depend on the preferred debt bias option either. As shown above, in order to design the preferred R&D option in a way to maintain at least current generosity levels, at least immediate expensing of all R&D costs needs to be ensured. As this means that R&D costs are not capitalised, there is no interaction between the generosity of the R&D incentive and the choice for the preferred debt bias option, which is the AGI.

5.5. The staged approach

This section presents (i) the impacts expected, relative to the CCCTB, from an initial stage without consolidation and formula apportionment (option 5a); and (ii) it assesses whether it would be opportune to foresee some form of cross-border loss offset during this initial stage (option 5b).

It is clear from this impact assessment and the one underpinning the 2011 proposal that the preferred option is the CCCTB. However, discussions in the Council have shown that the CCCTB is unlikely to be adopted in one piece, consolidation being the most difficult and controversial element. It no longer appears promising to move forward with the CCCTB in one single go and the Commission therefore decided to pursue a pragmatic approach, postponing the work on consolidation until after the common base has been agreed and implemented. Therefore this section presents the economic and fairness impacts of the initial stage, in which the common base is implemented. This means that provisions on profit and loss consolidation within groups and formula apportionment across Member States would be postponed. All other features of the base definition, notably an allowance for growth and investment (AGI) and R&D incentives would be the same in the common base and the CCCTB.

The comparison of options in this subsection concerns merely the possible inclusion of some form of cross-border loss offset, if the political environment required the staged approach for the introduction of the CCCTB. The main difference between cross-border loss offset and consolidation is that the latter would fully offset losses and profits within a CCCTB group whereas cross-border loss offset would only allow a vertical offset between parents and subsidiaries. In addition, the cross-border loss offset envisaged would foresee a reincorporation of the loss offset after some time.

5.5.1. Economic impacts

Table 16 presents the results from the CORTAX simulations for the common base with and without cross-border loss offset as well as, for comparison, the results for the CCCTB. All the simulations presented assume that all multinational enterprises apply the common base and that the common base includes the ACE/AGI to address the debt

bias. 104 It is clear that the CCCTB is expected to achieve better economic results than the

common base. GDP, investment, wages and employment all perform better. In the model, three main effects drive these differences in the impacts. First, under the CCCTB compliance costs are assumed to fall to zero for subsidiaries of multinational enterprises,

whereas they stay the same as before under the common base. 105 Second, consolidation

allows for the immediate offset of losses against profits made somewhere else in a multinational group. This lowers the tax burden and the cost of labour and the cost of capital. Third, the move to formula apportionment removes an important distortion to the location of real factors and replaces it by another, yet less significant, distortion induced by formula apportionment (see discussion Section 5.1). Overall, since in the CORTAX model the key economic benefits of the reform are driven by the ACE/AGI reform, the relative differences between the common base and the CCCTB are relatively minor.

Turning to the cross-border loss offset, CORTAX results indicate a fairly modest positive economic impact of allowing cross-border loss relief, where parents can claim losses of their subsidiaries. The most important benefit from offering some cross-border loss relief is the enhancement of cash-flow capacity of businesses (for instance, by compensating start-up losses in a Member State with profits in another Member State) and the resulting support for cross-border investment within the EU.

Currently only a few Member States offer limited forms of cross-border loss compensation. Some cross-border loss offset would alleviate in most Member States differences in the treatment of groups operating cross-border and domestic groups. Moreover, limited or non-existing cross-border loss offset implies differences in tax treatment of foreign permanent establishments and foreign subsidiaries. As the 2011 impact assessment notes, other potential benefits include the reduced risk of investment, as losses are better insured, and increased efficiency in the international allocation of productive capital.

Table 16: Economic impacts of an initial stage without consolidation, with and without cross-border loss relief –

multinational entities only + ACE/AGI, EU-28, GDP-weighted average

Common base Common base with cross-border loss relief CCCTB

Cost of capital

(change in percentage points) -0.29 -0.35 -0.32

Investment 3.06 3.62 3.36

Wages 0.88 1.11 1.26

Employment 0.40 0.52 0.65

GDP 1.06 1.31 1.17

Welfare (% of GDP) 0.19 0.22 0.18

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

Note: Changes are in % unless noted otherwise

104 R&D incentives should also apply but these do currently not feature in the CORTAX model.

105 A sensitivity analysis, in which the compliance costs instead are reduced by 50% is also performed in the CORTAX study.

Impact on administrative burden

The administrative burden would be reduced by much more under the CCCTB compared to the common base. Consolidation brings major benefits in terms of reduced compliance costs, eliminating the necessity to comply with the arm's length principle. For groups, the absence of consolidation implies that cross-border transactions between group members and associated enterprises would continue to be subject to transfer pricing rules and filing formalities. It would therefore be necessary to work out arm's length adjustments. In addition, groups of companies would have to continue dealing with as many tax administrations as the number of Member States where they have a taxable presence (i.e. subsidiary or permanent establishment). On the other hand, formula apportionment requires documenting additional information on the factors used in each company entity

in order to apply the formula. 106

Thus the CCCTB is expected to be particularly effective in reducing recurrent tax compliance cost. In terms of one-off costs for setting up a subsidiary in a new location, the common base would already constitute a major improvement as a company expanding cross-border would not have to deal with a new tax system. Tax administrations would be able to benefit from a reduced number of cases and fewer dealings with transfer pricing issues only once the CCCTB is implemented.

5.5.2. Fairness impacts

Consolidation and apportionment is clearly an important element to reap all the benefits from reducing tax avoidance. Whereas the common base would address profit shifting by exploiting patent boxes and mismatches in the tax systems, the CCCTB would in addition render profit shifting via transfer pricing and debt shifting unattractive (assuming that both the common base and the CCCTB would be mandatory for the most relevant companies).

A mechanism for a cross-border loss relief outside formula apportionment may give rise to new opportunities of tax planning and profit shifting in favour of multinational companies. Anti-tax avoidance provisions that may be implemented in order to prevent an abusive use of cross-border loss relief could have only limited dissuasive effect. It should also be underlined that tax administrations would have a crucial role in order to prevent abuses. Hence, anti-avoidance provisions could remain ineffective to the extent that tax administrations are not capable to apply them.

The loss relief should therefore have a narrow scope to minimise possibilities for tax avoidance. Notably, to safeguard national tax revenues, the deducted losses should be reincorporated ('recaptured') automatically if this has not occurred after a certain number of years or if the requisites to qualify as an immediate subsidiary or permanent establishment are no longer met. In addition, it should be ensured that companies cannot artificially reduce their tax bill by buying loss-making companies. This is an issue that has already been recognised in national systems that provide a loss relief for groups and can be addressed via specific anti-avoidance rules.

106 The required information concerns sales by destination, tangible fixed assets, employees and the wage bill.

5.5.3. Stakeholder views

More than 50% of companies who responded are in favour of a temporary cross-border loss relief. The positive view is shared by large companies and SMEs alike. The majority of the companies argue that the current lack of mechanisms available to offset crossborder losses is one of the major obstacles to the completion of the single market and reduces the competitiveness of the EU. A few respondents suggest that the cross-border loss offset should be extended to non-EU companies and permanent establishments, given that competitiveness of EU companies needs to be regarded on a global scale.

A strong majority of respondents from business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms believe that consolidation is essential. However, they would accept a transitory and temporary cross-border loss relief as a second-best approach. Some envisage resistance from Member States in offering wide-ranging cross-border relief as taxes should be paid where value is created. Others advocate the introduction of an EU wide regime, not linked to the CCCTB, to be implemented into domestic legislation.

Conversely, most NGOs and civil society organizations do not support a temporary mechanism for cross-border loss relief. They fear it would only shrink the taxable base of multinational companies and open up the system to new types of aggressive tax planning while postponing consolidation would remove the main benefit of the proposal.

5.5.4. Conclusion on staged approach

Should an initial stage without consolidation be required politically, a limited form of cross-border loss offset (option 5b) could have small positive impacts on key economic variables such as GDP, the labour market and investment.

5.6. Impact on SMEs

SMEs would be effectively excluded from the mandatory application of the CCCTB through the recommended high turnover threshold. Given the low degree of internationalisation of SMEs, the risk of imposing an additional administrative burden (through a change in the tax rules to which they would be subjected) would not necessarily be offset by the benefits of having a common base throughout the EU. However, the CCCTB is expected to support growth and investment and to reduce compliance costs when expanding across border. SMEs might therefore want to opt into the system, which would allow them to benefit from the CCCTB, including the AGI and the allowance for R&D expenses.

Indeed 63% of SMEs that responded to the public consultation are in favour of providing the possibility to opt into the CCCTB. Views by SMEs on other issues have been summarised above in the respective sections on the public consultation.

The impact of debt bias measures is likely to be higher for SMEs that would opt for the CCCTB. The debt bias is particularly detrimental for young and innovative firms, whose access to external funding is more difficult. Among the options, the AGI could potentially be particularly favourable to growing companies, which are likely to be small on average. Caiumi (2015) investigates the impact of the Italian ACE on the debt bias and finds that the corrective effect is particularly strong for SMEs.

5.7. Social and environmental impacts

There are no relevant environmental impacts expected from any of the options. Social impacts will also be limited, but two aspects are worth mentioning. To the extent that positive indirect impacts on the labour market materialise (employment and wages), positive social impacts are also expected. This aspect lends further support for a CCCTB with an AGI, which has the most positive impacts on the labour market.

In addition, the significant reduction of corporate tax avoidance under the CCCTB is expected to influence positively general taxpayer morale. The positive impact on taxpayer morale is maximized with a CCCTB and a mandatory scope that ensures that the major share of corporate tax avoidance is no longer feasible.

In the longer term, the provision of R&D tax incentives in the CCCTB which would lead to more investment in R&D could improve the living standard by generating positive social spillovers. Cost-benefit analyses of the social effects of R&D tax incentives carried

out in the Netherlands, Canada and Japan find positive effect on welfare. 107

5.8. Conclusion on the preferred option

5.8.1. Design components of the preferred option

The analysis of impacts in the previous sections focusses on three design elements of the CCCTB proposal. These elements were added to the 2011 proposal to address the new general and specific objectives outlined in Section 3. The general objectives are to (1) enhance the fairness of the tax system and to (2) stimulate growth and investment. Section 5.1 shows that the CCCTB offers clear advantages in comparison with the baseline scenario. The anticipated effects of enhancing fairness via reduced corporate tax avoidance, ensuring a fair tax contribution from the corporate sector, a more level playing field among companies and the expected positive impacts on taxpayer morale are critical, even if not all of them are quantifiable. Small positive economic and investment effects arise, notably by removing obstacles in the single market. Overall, welfare is expected to increase slightly. The impact on public finances will largely depend on how Member States will adjust tax rates, but also on some calibration issues such as the rate for the AGI. Under the assumption of partly offsetting changes in CIT rates, the simulations show a small decrease in total tax revenues by 0.2% of GDP, due to a reduction in CIT revenues partly offset by an increase in other taxes as a result of the increased economic activity. However, these figures do not capture expected positive impacts from closing important tax planning channels.

107 Parsons and Phillips (2007) conclude that the tax incentive in Canada had a positive welfare effect of eleven cents for every dollar spent in terms of lost tax revenue. Lokshin and Mohnen (2009) conclude that the Dutch program resulted in a 16% net welfare gain. Such analyses are sensitive to the assumptions made, for example on spillover rate and administrative and compliance costs.

Effectively reducing tax avoidance by multinational entities and increasing fairness through a more level playing field in the EU can only be reached if the relevant companies have to operate under a CCCTB. Section 5.2 concludes that a scope which is mandatory for a defined set of multinational entities and optional for other companies is the preferred option. The limit of compulsory application is set to groups with a high consolidated turnover. A threshold of EUR 750 million would serve the purpose of capturing the vast majority (ca. 64%) of turnover generated by groups while limiting the risk of including purely domestic groups. Furthermore, such a threshold would be coherent with the approach taken in current EU initiatives to enhance tax transparency.

Solutions for the CCCTB to address the debt bias in corporate taxation are analysed in Section 5.3. The options to address the debt bias are assessed not only based on their economic merits of removing the distortion, but also with a view to minimising the risks of tax planning. The allowance for growth and investment (AGI) is identified as the option that best matches both criteria. Compared to the CCCTB without AGI, the results also show much larger positive impacts in terms of overall investment which increases by up to 3.4% depending on the level of allowance.

Section 5.4 analyses the question of the appropriate level for an allowance for R&D investments. When setting the level of the allowance, policy makers have to weigh the increase in R&D expenses from granting the allowance with the loss of tax revenue. The simulations show that an additional allowance between 33% and 100% (i.e. beyond full immediate expensing) would be preferable to maintain or further encourage R&D investment in the EU at a reasonable cost. Allowances will reduce the tax bases and therefore revenues. However, costly and inefficient existing patent box regimes in Member States would be removed with the CCCTB. This could partly offset some of the revenue losses.

In conclusion, a mandatory CCCTB for very large companies, an AGI with welldesigned anti-avoidance measures and an R&D tax incentive designed as a super allowance for R&D expenses define the preferred option for the re-launch of the CCCTB.

5.8.2. Regulatory fitness and simplification of the preferred option

Tax compliance costs are an important burden for businesses and their reduction will be a major advantage of the implementation of the CCCTB. Estimated compliance costs for large companies amount to about 2% of taxes paid, while for SMEs the estimate was about 30% of taxes paid. Compliance costs are estimated to increase with cross-border activity and with increasing number of subsidiaries. Tax reform data show that numerous CIT reforms took place after the crisis and many measures were directed at reinforcing the international anti-abuse framework. In the light of this, the reduction of compliance costs when setting up an additional subsidiary when the CCCTB is introduced remains a major advantage: The compliance costs for companies will decline for those cases where cross-border investments are involved – partly because of the abolition of transfer pricing documentation, more generally because there is only one set of rules to comply with. Given the fact that the CCCTB is more streamlined than national systems, one could expect that also domestic compliance costs are reduced. In any case, the choice to enter the CCCTB will reflect compliance cost considerations, both for domestic firms and for multinational entities not subject to mandatory application. Generally, data on these questions are scarce or in some cases missing. The available survey data point however to cost savings as explained in Section 5.1.1 and therefore serves the objective to increase regulatory fitness. Time costs for setting up a new subsidiary in a Member State are estimated to decrease 62-67% for the CCCTB. Focussing on recurring costs, i.e. ignoring one-off switching costs, the Impact Assessment estimates a decrease in time spent on compliance activities by 8% after implementation of the CCCTB. Based on these time reductions one could endeavour a rough calculation of the order of total cost savings that would result under the CCCTB. If 5% of medium-sized companies expand abroad, a oneoff cost saving of around EUR 1 billion could be expected. If all multinational entities apply the CCCTB recurring compliance costs could go down by about EUR 0.8 billion.

With regard to the costs of tax administrations, the parallel application of national CIT systems and the CCCTB will increase administrative burden in tax administrations since two, albeit similar taxes need to be managed. However, since multinational entities under the scope of the CCCTB will file only one tax declaration in the EU the total amount of tax declarations should decline and ease the burden for tax administrations. Also, the fact that no more transfer pricing documentation is necessary in the EU will reduce the burden on administrations – in line with increasing regulatory fitness.

5.9. Choice of the corresponding policy instrument

It is beyond doubt that binding legal rules are necessary for providing solutions, through a common legislative framework, to the problems identified earlier as distortions to the single market. Soft law would risk not being implemented by Member States at all or could lead to a piece-meal approach. Such an outcome would be highly undesirable. In addition to creating legal uncertainty for taxpayers, non-binding rules could jeopardise the objectives for a coordinated and coherent corporate tax system in the single market. In addition, as the architecture of the common tax base should be expected to impact on national budgets, especially through the formula apportionment, it is critical that the rules which define its composition be applied consistently and efficiently. This is far more likely to be achieved through binding law.

Based on Article 115 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU), which is the legal base used for legislating in direct taxation, "the Council shall, acting unanimously … issue directives for the approximation of laws, regulations and administrative provisions of the Member States as directly affect the establishment or functioning of the internal market." The Treaty is therefore prescriptive that in direct taxation, legislation shall exclusively be in the form of directives. According to Article 288 TFEU, a directive shall be binding, as to the result to be achieved, upon each Member State to which it is addressed, but shall leave to the national authorities the choice of form and methods for achieving this result. In this vein, the directive should remain general in nature since technicalities and the minute detail should be left to Member States to decide.

  • 6. 
    M ONITORING AND EVALUATION

    6.1. Monitoring arrangements

The Commission will monitor the implementation of the legal proposal and its application in close cooperation with the Member States. Monitoring in a continuous and systematic way will allow identifying whether the policy proposal is applied as expected and addressing implementation problems in a timely manner. Collection of factual data of the suggested monitoring indicators will also provide the basis for the future evaluation of the CCCTB. Given the specificities of the proposal, the monitoring will cover both phases of the staged approach set out in the preferred option.

In terms of operational objectives, the number of intra-EU profit shifting arrangements should be significantly reduced compared to the status quo since the CCCTB makes the

current practices obsolete. 108 The corresponding indicators presented in Table 17 are a

selection of those suggested by the OECD/G20 BEPS project (Action 11), slightly modified to fit the context of the CCCTB initiative. For other companies the CCCTB is optional, but it is generally designed to be attractive for all businesses. The operational goal is to have a large number of firms opting into the system, ideally from all sectors of the economy. The operational objective to ensure that profit taxation that does not distort financing decisions is (i) to reduce the difference in the cost of capital for debt and equity and (ii) to reduce the debt-equity ratio in companies. High take-up rates of the R&D tax incentives are the relevant operational objective to measure progress towards the goal to enhance investment in business R&D.

To measure the operational objectives, in-depth analyses is necessary. The data needed is micro-panel data for companies, as well as national accounts data and information from tax administrations, for instance on the take-up of the R&D allowance under the CCCTB. To measure the effects econometrically a period of five years after the introduction is necessary to produce statistically relevant results.

In compliance with the principle of subsidiarity, the relevant information should be gathered primarily by the Member States' tax administrations when data on tax compliance and the use of the system is concerned. Micro-data on companies is available from external data providers.

108 For the status quo see the study by Ramboll et al. (2015) on aggressive tax planning structures as well as ZEW (2016c).

Table 17: Potential monitoring indicators

Operational Objective Indicators

• Concentration of foreign direct investment relative to GDP

• Effective tax rates of MNEs subject to mandatory application of the

  • 1. 
    Significantly reduce the common base/CCCTB relative to companies not applying the common number of intra-EU profit base/CCCTB with similar characteristics

    shifting arrangements • Concentration of royalty receipts relative to R&D spending

    • Interest-to-income ratios of MNE affiliates in locations with above

    average statutory tax rates

    • Number of companies who have opted for the common base/CCCTB

    • Number of companies who have opted-in or opted-out in a given year

  • 2. 
    Large number of companies • Number of companies who fall under the mandatory application of the

    opting in from all sectors common base/CCCTB

    • Contextual information: resident Member State, sector and size of the company; statutory and effective tax rates under the common

    base/CCCTB

    • Cost of capital for investments financed by debt and by equity for

  • 3. 
    Reduce difference in cost of companies applying the common base/CCCTB (by Member State) capital for debt and equity • Levels of debt and equity for companies applying the common

    base/CCCTB and for companies not applying the common base/CCCTB

    • Number of companies receiving an R&D allowance under the common

  • 4. 
    High take-up rates of base CCCTB

R&D incentives • R&D allowance granted under the common base/CCCTB by company

• Contextual information: sector and size of the company

Source: European Commission

Note: The data sources for indicator 1 are described in the final report on BEPS Action 11.

6.2. Evaluation

The evaluation of the CCCTB should assess the extent to which the outlined objectives have been met. It will also analyse the extent to which the expected simplifications for the targeted stakeholders have materialized and assess the related administrative and regulatory burden. Considering the phased approach of the CCCTB and allowing for impacts to materialize and to be observed after the implementation of the policy, an evaluation should be carried out three to five years after the implementation of the second phase of the proposal. The Commission will report on the evaluation results in the form of an evaluation report.

  • 7. 
    G LOSSARY

Aggressive tax planning (see also: Tax planning): In the Commission Recommendation on aggressive tax planning (C(2012) 8806 final), aggressive tax planning is defined as “taking advantage of the technicalities of a tax system or of mismatches between two or more tax systems for the purpose of reducing tax liability. Aggressive tax planning can take a multitude of forms. Its consequences include double deductions (e.g. the same loss is deducted both in the state of source and residence) and double non-taxation (e.g. income which is not taxed in the source state is exempt in the state of residence)”.

Allowance for corporate capital (ACC) is a corporate tax system where corporations may deduct a defined return on total capital (both equity and debt) from the corporate income tax base. It achieves full financing neutrality between debt and equity at the corporate level.

Allowance for corporate equity (ACE) is a corporate tax system where interest payments and a defined return on equity can both be deducted from the corporate income tax base. It moves the system closer to financing neutrality between debt and equity at the corporate level.

Allowance for growth and investment (AGI) is a corporate tax system where interest payments and a return on equity can both be deducted from the corporate income tax base. It moves the system closer to financing neutrality between debt and equity at the corporate level. It goes some steps further than ACE because it removes tax avoidance by cascading the benefits (the funds injected in a group benefit from deductibility only once) and uses an incremental system based on a moving reference year.

Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive (ATAD) is an EU Tax Directive which lays down rules against tax avoidance practices which directly affect the functioning of the single market.

Anti-Tax Avoidance Package (ATAP) is a package of actions which includes legallybinding anti-avoidance measures necessary to reduce aggressive tax planning. It is part of the action plan on corporate taxation for fairer, simpler and more effective corporate taxation in the EU.

Base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS project): Tax planning strategies that exploit gaps and mismatches in tax rules to artificially shift profits to low or no-tax locations where there is little or no economic activity, resulting in little or no overall corporate tax being paid. The OECD and the EU have developed specific actions to give countries the tools they need to ensure that profits are taxed where economic activities generating the profits are performed and where value is created, while at the same time giving enterprises greater certainty by reducing disputes over the application of international tax rules, and standardising requirements.

Common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) is a policy proposal of the European Commission consisting of the harmonisation of the tax base of corporations at EU level. It also includes consolidation and apportionment of the tax base of corporation groups.

Common corporate tax base (CCTB) consists of the harmonisation of the tax base of corporations at the EU level, but does not include the element of tax consolidation which is part of the CCCTB.

Comprehensive business income tax (CBIT) refers to a corporate tax system where neither interest payments nor the return on equity can be deducted from corporate profits, and are thus both fully subject to corporate income tax. It equalises the tax treatment of debt and equity finance at the corporate level.

Controlled foreign corporation (CFC) is a foreign corporation whose income (or some part of it) is deemed to be generated (and hence to be taxed) in the residence country of the multinational group if certain conditions are met (usually this condition is that the tax rate in the foreign country is lower than a set percentage of the tax rate in the country implementing the CFC rule). The particular definition of the foreign corporations subject to these rules varies across jurisdictions, but it is generally based on a control percentage.

Corporate income tax (CIT) is a direct tax levied on the profits of corporations. The tax rate payable varies across jurisdictions.

Cost of capital (CoC) is a measure of the cost of either debt and/or equity. It is used to assess the cost of new investments.

Cost of capital allowance (CoCA): The term refers to a corporate tax system where the cost for both debt and equity finance is captured by a defined allowance which is deductible from the corporate tax base; similarly, at the investor's level, the income tax base increases by a defined return on the investments, which corresponds to the defined allowance and can be taxable. The amount of the allowance/return is computed as the product of the relevant assets/investments multiplied by a CoCA rate. This system equalises the tax treatment of debt and equity finance at the corporate and investor level.

Country-by-country reporting (CBCR) refers to the requirement that large multinational entities (those with consolidated revenues of at least EUR 750 million) have to submit a report on tax-related information to the jurisdictions in which they do business on an annual basis.

Debt-equity tax bias/debt bias can be the result of operating a corporate tax system which favours financing by debt, rather than by equity. This is achieved by treating interest payments as a tax deductible expense whilst no equivalent deduction is granted for the return on equity (mainly, dividends).

Double taxation is an international taxation scenario in which the same taxable object is subject to taxation in two or more jurisdictions.

Earnings before interest, tax depreciation and amortisation (EBITDA) is an accounting measure of the net earnings of a company. It excludes interest, taxes, depreciation and amortisation expenses.

Effective average tax rate is a tax rate calculated from the nominal tax rate and the definition of the tax base. Particularly, this effective tax rate is based on total investment income.

Effective marginal tax rate is a tax rate calculated from the combination of the nominal (i.e. statutory) tax rate and the definition of the tax base (i.e. the taxable profit). Particularly, this effective tax rate is based on additional investment income.

Formula apportionment is an equation used to allocate the tax base of multinational corporations between the entities of the group.

Hybrid mismatches: This refers to the situation where, as a result of disparities amongst national laws, the same entity or financial instrument is characterized differently, as far as its tax treatment is concerned, in two or more States (e.g. an entity is treated as a partnership in one jurisdiction and as a corporation in another; a financial instrument qualifies as deductible interest in one jurisdiction and as tax exempt dividend in the other). Taxpayers often set up arrangements to exploit such mismatches for the purpose of lowering their overall tax burden.

Intellectual property is a set of intangible assets owned by a company, which are legally protected by patents, trademarks, copyrights or other type of intellectual property rights.

Joint Transfer Pricing Forum is an EU forum of experts that assists and advises the European Commission on transfer pricing tax issues. It was created by a Commission's

Decision of 25 th January 2011. 109 The JTPF has one representative from each Member

State's tax administrations and 18 non-government organisation members. It is chaired by an independent chairperson. The JTPF works within the framework of the OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines and operates on the basis of consensus to propose to the Commission pragmatic, non-legislative solutions to practical problems posed by transfer pricing practices in the EU.

Multinational entities/companies/enterprises are corporations that operate across different jurisdictions.

Non-financial corporations are corporations not belonging to the financial sector.

Profit shifting is an intra-group tax planning strategy of multinational entities consisting of shifting profits from the entities of the group operating in high tax paying countries to other entities operating in low tax paying countries.

Research & Development (R&D):

Research: all original and planned investigation undertaken with the prospect of gaining new scientific or technical knowledge and understanding.

Development: the application of research findings or other knowledge to a plan or design for the production of new or substantially improved materials, products, devices, processes, systems or services before the start of commercial production or use.

Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are defined by the European Commission as having less than 250 persons employed. They should also have an annual turnover of up to EUR 50 million, or a balance sheet total of no more than EUR 43 million (Commission Recommendation of 6 May 2003).

109 http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/taxation/company_tax/transfer_pricing/forum/c_2011_16_en.pdf

Special-purpose entities are legal entities established to perform specific functions limited in scope or time, which has little or no production, is often a subsidiary and has as a core business function financing its group activities or holding assets and liabilities of its group.

Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) is one of the Treaties on which the EU is founded. It organises the functioning of the Union and determines the areas of, delimitation of, and arrangements for exercising its competences.

Tax avoidance: According to the OECD glossary of tax terms, tax avoidance is defined as the arrangement of a taxpayer’s affairs in a way that is intended to reduce his or her tax liability and that - although the arrangement may be strictly legal - is usually in contradiction with the intent of the law it purports to follow.

Tax evasion: According to the OECD glossary of tax terms, tax evasion is defined as illegal arrangements where the liability to tax is hidden or ignored. This implies that the taxpayer pays less tax than he or she is legally obligated to pay by hiding income or information from the tax authorities.

Tax planning (see also: Aggressive tax planning): According to the OECD glossary of tax terms, tax planning is an arrangement of a person’s business and/or private affairs in order to minimize tax liability.

  • 8. 
    R EFERENCES

Agúndez-García, A. (2006), 'The Delineation and Apportionment of an EU Consolidated Tax Base for Multi-jurisdictional Corporate Income Taxation: A Review of Issues and Options', Taxation Papers No 9, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Alstadsæter, A., Barrios, S., Nicodeme, G., Skonieczna, A. and Vezzani, A. (2015), 'Patent Boxes Design, Patents Location and Local R&D', Taxation Papers No 57, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Arundel, A. (2001), 'The relative effectiveness of patents and secrecy for appropriation', Research Policy, 30(4), pp. 611-624.

Aus dem Moore, N. (2014a), 'Taxes and Corporate Financing Decisions: Evidence from the Belgian ACE Reform', Ruhr Economic Papers, No 533, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (RWI).

Aus dem Moore, N. (2014b), 'Corporate Taxation and Investment: Evidence from the Belgian ACE Reform', Ruhr Economic Papers, No 534, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (RWI).

Balasubramanian, N. and J. Sivadasan (2011), 'What Happens When Firms Patent? New Evidence from U.S. Economic Census Data', The Review of Economics and Statistics, No 93(1), pp. 126-146.

Bao, D.-H. and Romeo, G. C. (2013), 'Tax Avoidance and Corporations in the United States – The Effective Tax Rate Abnormality for the Top Five Percent by Corporate Size', Journal of Applied Business and Economics 14(4), pp. 88-100.

Belz, T., von Hagen, D. and Steffens, C. (2016), 'Taxes and Firm Size: Political Cost or Political Power? A Meta-Regression Analysis', SSRN Working paper.

Becker, B. (2015), 'Public R&D policies and private R&D investment: a survey of the empirical evidence', Journal of Economic Surveys 29(5), pp. 917-942.

Bénassy-Quéré, A., Trannoy, A. and Wolff, G. (2014), 'Tax Harmonization in Europe: Moving Forward', Les notes du CAE, 14, July, Conseil d'analyse économique (CAE), Paris.

Bettendorf, L. and van der Horst, A. (2006), 'Documentation of CORTAX', CPB Memorandum No 161, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis.

Bettendorf, L., van der Horst, A. and de Mooij, R. (2009a), 'Corporate Tax Policy and Unemployment in Europe: An Applied General Equilibrium Analysis', The World Economy, pp. 1319-1347.

Bettendorf, L., van der Horst, A., de Mooij, R., Devereux, M and Loretz, S. (2009b), 'The economic effects of EU-reforms in corporate income systems', Study for the European Commission Directorate General for Taxation and Customs Union.

Bettendorf, L., Devereux, M., van der Horst, A., Loretz, S. and de Mooij, R. (2010a), 'Corporate tax harmonization in the EU', Economic Policy, pp. 537–590.

Bettendorf, L., van der Horst, A., de Mooij, R. and Vrijburg, H. (2010b), 'Corporate Tax Consolidation and Enhanced Cooperation in the European Union', Fiscal Studies, Vol. 31, No 4, pp. 453–479.

Bloom, N., Schankerman, M. and van Reenen, J. (2013), 'Identifying Technology Spillovers and Product Market Rivalry.' Econometrica, Vol 81, No 4, pp. 1347–1393.

Blouin, J., Huizinga, H., Laeven, L. and Nicodeme, G. (2014), 'Thin Capitalization Rules and Multinational Firm Capital Structure', Taxation papers No 42, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Boadway R. and Bruce, N. (1984), 'A General Proposition On The Design of a Neutral Business Tax', Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 24, No 2, pp. 231-239.

Büttner, T., Riedel, N., and Runkel, M. (2011), 'Strategic Consolidation under Formula Apportionment', National Tax Journal, Vol. 64, 2011, pp. 225-254.

Büttner, T., Overesch, M., Schreiber, U. and Wamser, G. (2012), 'The Impact of Thin Capitalization Rules on the Capital Structure of Multinational Firms', Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 96 No 11, pp. 930-938.

Bravo-Biosca, A., Criscuolo, C. and Menon, C. (2013), 'What Drives the Dynamics of Business Growth?', OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers, No. 1, OECD Publishing.

Cecchetti, S. G., Mohanty, M. and Zampolli, F. (2011), 'The real effects of debt', Economic Symposium Conference Proceedings, Jackson Hole, pp- 145-196.

Chang, A. (2014), 'Tax Policy Endogeneity: Evidence from R&D Tax Credits'. Finance and Economics Discussion Series, No 2014-101, Federal Reserve Board.

Cincera, M. and Veugelers, R. (2013), 'Young leading innovators and the EU's R&D intensity gap', Economics of Innovation and New Technology Vol. 22 No 2, pp. 177-198.

Clausing, K. A. (2011), 'The revenue effects of multinational form income shifting', Tax Notes.

Clausing, K.A., and Lahav, Y. (2011), 'Corporate tax payments under formulary apportionment: Evidence from the financial reports of 50 major U.S. multinational firms', Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, Vol. 20, 2011, pp. 97-105.

CPB (2014), 'A study on R&D tax incentives. Final Report.' Taxation Papers, No 52, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Criscuolo C, Bajgar M, Appelt S, Galindo-Rueda F (2016), R&D tax incentives: design and evidence. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris, No DSTI/IND/STP (2016)

De Mooij, R. (2011a), 'Tax Biases to Debt Finance: Assessing the Problem, Finding Solutions', May 2011, IMF Staff Discussion Note, No 11/11, International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington D.C.

De Mooij, R. (2011b), 'The Tax Elasticity of Corporate Debt; A Synthesis of Size and Variations', IMF Working Paper, No 11/95, International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington D.C.

De Mooij R. A. and Devereux, M. P. (2011c), 'An applied analysis of ACE and CBIT reforms in the EU', International Tax and Publix Finance, Vol. 18 No 1, pp. 93-120.

De Mooij R. A., (2012), 'Tax Biases to Debt Finance: Assessing the Problem, Finding Solutions', Fiscal Studies Vol. 33 No 4, pp. 489–512.

De Moiij, R., Keen, M. and Orihara, M. (2014), 'Taxation, Bank Leverage, and Financial Crises', Taxation and Regulation of the Financial Sector, de Mooij and Nicodeme (eds.), MIT Press, Cambridge, chapter 11.

Devereux, M.P. and Freeman, H. (1991), 'A General Neutral Profits Tax', Fiscal Studies, Vol. 12 No 3, pp. 1-15.

Devereux, M. P. and Griffith, R. (1998a), 'Taxes and the location of production: evidence from a penal of US multinationals', Journal of Public Economics Vol. 68 No 3, pp. 335- 367.

Devereux, M. P. and Griffith, R. (1998b), 'The Taxation of Discrete Investment Choices', IFS Working Paper, No W98/16, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London.

Devereux, M.P. and Griffith, R. (2003), 'Evaluating tax policy for location decisions', International Tax and Public Finance, No 10, pp. 107-126.

Devereux, M.P., Maffini, G. and Xing, J. (2015), 'Corporate tax incentives and capital structure: empirical evidence from UK tax returns', Working Papers, No 1507, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation.

Dharmapala, D. (2014), 'What do we know about base erosion and profit shifting? A review of the empirical literature', Fiscal Studies, Vol. 35, 2014, pp. 421-448.

Egger, P., Eggert, W. and Winner, H. (2010), 'Saving Taxes through Foreign Plant Ownership', Journal of International Economics 81(1), pp. 99-108.

Eichfelder, S., Hechtner, F., Hundsdoerfer, J. (2015), 'Formula Apportionment: Factor Allocation and Tax Avoidance', Arbeitskreis Quantitative Steuerlehre (arqus), Discussion paper No. 199.

Eichfelder, S. and Vaillancourt, F. (2014), 'Tax Compliance Costs: A Review of Cost Burdens and Cost Structures', arqus Working Paper 178, Arbeitskreis Quantitative Steuerlehre, Berlin 2014.

European Central Bank (2014), 'Deleveraging patterns in the euro area corporate sector', ECB Monthly Bulletin, February 2014, European Central Bank, Frankfurt.

European Commission (2001), 'Company taxation in the Internal market', SEC (2001) 1681, Brussels.European Commission (2006), 'Towards a more effective use of tax incentives in favour of R&D', Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament and the European Economic and Social Committee, No COM/2006/0728 final.

European Commission (2011a), 'Impact Assessment - Accompanying document to the Proposal for a Council Directive on a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB)', Commission Staff Working Document, SEC(2011) 315 final, European Commission, Brussels.

European Commission (2011b), 'Opportunities for the Internationalisation of European SMEs – Final Report', Directorate-General for Internal Market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs.

European Commission (2015a), 'A Fair and Efficient Corporate Tax System in the European Union: 5 Key Areas for Action', Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and The Council, COM(2015) 302 final i, European Commission, Brussels.

European Commission (2015b), 'Corporate Income Taxation in the European Union', Commission Staff Working Document, SWD(2015) 121 final, European Commission, Brussels.

European Commission (2015c), 'Internationalisation of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises', Flash Eurobarometer 421, Directorate-General for Internal Market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs.

European Commission (2016), 'Science, Research and Innovation performance of the EU. A contribution to the Open Innovation, Open Science, Open to the World agenda'. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2016.

Evans, C. Hansford, A., Hasseldine, J., Lignier, P., Smulders, S. and Vaillancourt, F. (2014), 'Small business and tax compliance costs: A cross-country study of managerial benefits and tax concessions', eJournal of Tax Research. Vol 12, no. 2, pp. 453-482.

Evers, L., Miller, H. and Spengel, C. (2015), 'Intellectual property box regimes: effective tax rates and tax policy considerations', International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 22, pp. 502-530.

Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1999), "The Corporate Cost of Capital and the Return on Corporate Investment," The Journal of Finance, No. 6.

Fatica, S., Hemmelgarn, T. and Nicodeme, G. (2013), 'The Debt-Equity Bias: Consequences and Solutions', Reflets et Perspectives de la Vie Economique, Vol. 52 No 1, pp. 5-18.

Financial Stability Board (2015), Corporate Funding Structures and Incentives – Final Report, Basel, August 2015

Finke, K. (2013), Tax Avoidance of German Multinationals and Implications for Tax Revenue Evidence from a Propensity Score Matching Approach, mimeo.

Fortin B., Lacroix G. and Villeval, M-C. (2007), 'Tax evasion and social interactions', Journal of Public Economics Vol. 91 No 11-12, pp. 2089–2112.

Garnier, G., György, E., Heineken, K., Mathé, M., Puglisi, L., Rua, S., et al. (2014), 'A wind of change? Reforms of Tax Systems since the launch of Europe 2020'. Taxation Papers No 49, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Giannini, S. and Maggiulli, C. (2002), 'The Effective Tax Rates in the EU Commission Study on Corporate Taxation: Methodological Aspects, Main Results and Policy Implications', CESifo Working Papers, No 666, CESifo Group, München.

Gordon, R. and Wilson, J.D. (1986), 'An Examination of Multijurisdictional Corporate Income Taxation under Formula Apportionment', Econometrica, Vol. 54, No. 6, 1986, pp. 1357-1373.

Griffith, R., Miller, H., and O'Connell, M. (2014). 'Ownership of intellectual property and corporate taxation'. Journal of Public Economics Vol. 112, pp. 12–23.

Gropp, R. and Heider, F. (2010), 'The determinants of bank capital structure', Review of Finance Vol. 14, No 4, pp. 587-622.

Hasegawa, M., Hopes, J. L., Ishida, R., and Slemrod, J. B. (2013), 'The effect of public disclosure on reported taxable income: Evidence from individuals and corporations in Japan', National Tax Journal Vol. 66 No 3, pp. 571-608.

Hall, B.H., Mairesse, J. and Mohnen, P. (1999), 'Measuring the Returns to R&D', in: Handbook of the Economics of Innovation (edited by B.H. Hall and N. Rosenberg). Vol. 1, Elsevier, 2010.

Hall, B., Helmers, C., Rogers, M., Sena, V. (2013), 'The importance (or not) of patents to UK firms', NBER Working Paper Series, No 19089.

Hall, B., Helmers, C., Rogers, M., Sena, V. (2014), 'The choice between formal and informal intellectual property: A review', Journal of Economic Literature Vol. 52 No 2, pp. 375–423.

Hanel, P. (2008), 'The use of intellectual property rights an innovation by manufacturing firms in Canada', Economics of Innovation and New Technologies Vol 17, pp. 285-309.

Hebous, S. and Ruf, M. (2015), 'Evaluating the Effects of ACE Systems on Multinational Debt Financing and Investment', CESifo Working Paper, No 5360, CESifo Group, München.

Heckemeyer, J.H. and Overesch, M. (2013), 'Multinationals' profit response to tax differentials: Effect size and shifting channels', ZEW Discussion Paper, No 13-045, ZEW Centre for European Economic Research, Mannheim.

Hellerstein, W., (2005), 'Income Allocation in the 21st century: The End of Transfer Pricing? The Case for Formulary Apportionment', International Transfer Pricing Journal, Vol. 3.

Hellerstein, W., (2012), 'Tax Planning under the CCCTB's Formulary Apportionment Provisions: The Good, the bad, and the Ugly', Dennis Weber (ed.), CCCTB: Selected Issues, Kluwer Law International, 2012, pp. 221-252.

Hemmelgarn; T. and Teichmann, D. (2014), 'Tax reforms and the capital structure of banks', International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 21, No 4, pp. 645-693.

Huizinga, H., Laeven, L., and Nicodeme, G. (2008), 'Capital Structure and International Debt Shifting', Journal of Financial Economics Vol. 88 No 1, pp. 80-118.

Ilzkovitz, F. and Dierx, A. (2016), 'Competition Policy and Inclusive Growth', Voxeu.org of 19 June 2016.

International Monetary Fund (2009), 'Debt Bias and Other Distortions: Crisis-Related Issues in Tax Policy', Public Information Notice (PIN), No 09/76, June 2009, International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington D.C.

International Monetary Fund (2010), Financial Sector Taxation, the IMF Report to the G-20 and Background Material, Claessens, Keen and Pazarbasioglu (eds.), International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington D.C.

International Monetary Fund (2016), 'IMF Fiscal Monitor. Acting Now, Acting Together'. World economic and financial surveys, International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington, DC.

Joint Research Center of the European Commission (2016), Modelling corporate tax reform in the EU: New calibration and simulations with the CORTAX model, Report by the Joint Research Center.

Keen, M. and de Mooij, R. (2012), 'Debt, Taxes, and Banks', IMF Working Paper 12/48, International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington D.C.

Keser, C., Kimpel, G., Oestreicher, A., (2014), ' The CCCTB option an experimental study ' CIRANO Working Papers , 2014s-24.

Kind, H.J., Midelfart, K.H. and Schjelderup, G. (2005), 'Corporate Tax Systems, Multinational Enterprises and Economic Integration', Journal of International Economics, Vol. 65, 2005, pp. 507-521.

King, M., and Fullerton, D. (1984), 'The taxation of income from capital: a comparative study of the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden and West Germany', The Chicago University Press.

Kirchler E., Niemirowski A. and Wearing, A. (2006), 'Shared subjective views, intent to cooperate and tax compliance: Similarities between Australian taxpayers and tax officers', Journal of Economic Psychology, Vol. 27, No 4, pp. 502–517.

Langedijk, S., Nicodeme, G., Pagano, A., and Rossi, A. (2014), 'Debt Bias in Corporate Income Taxation and the Costs of Banking Crises', CEPR Discussion Paper, No 10616.

Lee L-E, M. Moscardi, G. Trivedi and Shakdwipee, M. (2015), 'Re‐Examining the Tax Gap – The Tax Gap in the MSCI World', Issue Brief, MSCI ESG Research, New York.

Kleinbard D. E. (2015), 'Reimagining capital income taxation', Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation Working paper Vol. 15, No 24.

Klemm, A. and Radaelli C. (2001), The reform of the EU tax system, Report of the Ceps tax task force, Centre for European Policy Studies, Brussels.

Koehler, C., Laredo, P., Rammer, C. (2012), "The Impact and Effectiveness of Fiscal Incentives for R&D", Nesta Working Paper No 12/01.

Lignier, P and Evans, C (2012), ‘The rise and rise of tax compliance costs for the small business sector in Australia’, Australian Tax Forum, No 27, pp. 615-672.

Lignier, P, Evans, C and Tran-Nam, B (2014), ‘Tangled up in tape: The continuing tax compliance plight of the small and medium enterprise business sector’, Australian Tax Forum, No 29, pp. 217-247.

Lokshin, B. and Mohnen, P., (2009). 'What does it take for an R&D tax incentive policy to be effective?' MERIT Working Papers.

McLure, Ch.E., Jr. (1980), 'The State Corporate Income Tax: Lambs in Wolves ́ Clothing', in H. J. Aaron and M. J. Boskin (eds.) The Economics of Taxation. Washington: Brookings Institution.

McLure, Ch.E., Jr. (2002), 'Replacing Separate Entity Accounting and the Arm's Length Principle with Formulary Apportionment', Bulletin for International Fiscal Documentation, Vol. 56, 2002, pp. 586-599.

Mintz, J. M. and Smart, M. (2004), 'Income Shifting, Investment and Tax Competition: Theory and Evidence from Provincial Taxation in Canada', Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 88, 2004, pp. 1149-1178.

Musgrave, P.B. (1973), 'International Tax Base Division and the Multinational Corporation', Public Finance, Vol. 27, 1973, pp. 394-411.

National Bank of Belgium (2008), Impact Macroéconomique et Budgétaire de la déduction Fiscale pour Capital à Risque, July 22.

Navaretti, G. B., Bugamelli, F., Chivardi, F., Altomonte, C., Horgos, D. and Maggioni, D. (2011), 'The Global Operations of European Firms – The Second EFIGE policy report', Bruegel Blueprints Series, Vol. XII, Bruegel, Brussels.

OECD (1991), 'Taxing Profits in the Global Economy: Domestic and International Issues', Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris.

OECD (2007), 'Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment: Recent Evidence and Policy Analysis', OECD Tax Policy Studies, No. 17.

OECD (2015a), 'How to Restore a Healthy Financial Sector that Supports Long-Lasting, Inclusive Growth?', Economics Department Policy Note, No 27, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris.

OECD (2015b), 'Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country Reporting, Action 13 - 2015 Final Report', OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris.

OECD (2015c), R&D Tax Incentive Indicators, www.oecd.org/sti/rd-tax-stats.htm and Main Science and Technology Indicators, www.oecd.org/sti/msti.htm, June 2015, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris.

OECD (2015d), Measuring and Monitoring BEPS: Action 11 – 2015 Final Report, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris.

OECD (2016), 'Fiscal incentives for R&D innovation and dissemination in a heterogeneous world', Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, Note by the Secretariat. Forthcoming as chapter in OECD's Business and Financial Outlook, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris.

Ortmann, R. and Erich, P. (2015), 'Formula Apportionment or Separate Accounting? Tax-Induced Distortions of Multinationals’ Locational Investment Decisions', TAF Working Paper, University of Paderborn.

Panteghini, P., Parisi, M.L. and Pighetti F. (2012), 'Italy's ACE Tax and its Effect on a Firm's Leverage', CESifo Working Paper, No 3869, CESifo Group, München.

Panier, F., Perez-Gonzalez, F. and Villanueva, P. (2015), 'Capital Structure and Taxes: What happens when you (also) subsidize equity?', Stanford University, Mimeo.

Parsons, M., and Phillips, N. (2007). 'An Evaluation of the Federal Tax Credit for Scientific Research and Experimental Development'. Working Paper, Department of Finance, Canada.

Poterba, J.M. (1998), 'The rate of return to corporate capital and factor shares: new estimates using revised national income accounts and capital stock data', Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy Vol. 48, No 21, pp. 211-246

Princen; S. (2012), 'Taxes do Affect Corporate Financing Decisions: The Case of Belgian ACE', CESifo Working Paper, No 3713, CESifo Group, München.

PwC. (2008), Impact of corporate income tax reforms at the EU level on European business taxpayers. Report on the impact on taxable profits.

Schäfer, A. and Spengel, C. (2003), 'The impact of ICT on Profit Allocation within Multinational Groups: Arm's Length Pricing or Formula Apportionment?', ZEW Discussion Paper No. 03-53, ZEW Centre for European Economic Research, Mannheim.

Scherer, F. M, Harhoff, D. (2000), 'Technology policy for a world of skew-distributed outcomes', Research Policy, Vol. 29, pp. 559-566.

Schepens, G. (2015), 'Taxes and Bank Capital Structure', available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2519533 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2519533.

Ramboll Management Consulting, The Evaluation Partnership and Europe Economic Research (2013), 'A review and Evaluation of Methodologies to calculate tax compliance costs', Taxation Papers, No 40, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Ramboll Management Consulting and Corit Advisory (2015), 'Study on Structures of Aggressive Tax Planning and Indicators', Taxation Papers, No 61, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Redoano, M. (2014), 'Tax competition among European countries. Does the EU matter?', European Journal of Policital Economy, No 34, pp. 353-371.

Sandford C., Godwin, M. and Hardwick, P. (1989), 'Administrative and compliance costs of taxation', Fiscal Publications, Bath.

Schreiber, U., Spengel. C. and Lammersen, L. (2002), 'Measuring the Impact of Taxation on Investment and Financing Decisions', Schmalenbach Business Review, Vol. 54, pp. 2- 23.

Silverberg, G. and Verspagen, B. (2007), 'The size distribution of innovations revisited: An application of extreme value statistics to citation and value measures of patent significance', Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 139 No. 2, pp. 318-339.

Sørensen P. B. (2015), Taxation and the Optimal Constraint on Corporate Debt Finance: Why a Comprehensive Business Income Tax is Suboptimal, University of Copenhagen.

Spengel, C. and Zöllkau, Y. (2012), Common Corporate Tax Base (CC(C)TB) and Determination of Taxable Income: An International Comparison, Springer, Berlin.

Squicciarini, M. and Dernis, H. (2013), 'A Cross-Country Characterisation of the Patenting Behaviour of Firms based on Matched Firm and Patent Data', OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, 2013/05, OECD Publishing.

Streif, F. (2015), 'Tax Competition in Europe – Europe in Competition with Other World Regions?', ZEW Discussion Paper, No 15-082, ZEW Centre for European Economic Research, Mannheim.

Sullivan, M. (2004), 'Data Show Dramatic Shift Of Profits to Tax Havens', Tax Notes, September 2004, Tax Analysts, pp. 1190-1200.

Sveikauskas, L. (2007), 'R&D and Productivity Growth: A Review of the Literature.' Bureau of Labor Statistics Working Paper 408, U.S. Department of Labor, Washington.

Thomsen, M., Ullmann, R., and Watrin, C. (2014), 'The impact of taxes on location decisions', Working Paper, University of Münster.

Torgler B., Demir I. C., Macintyre A. and Schaffner, M. (2008), 'Causes and Consequences of Tax Morale: An Empirical Investigation', Economic Analysis and Policy, Vol. 38 No 2, pp. 313-339.

VVA and ZEW (2015), SME taxation in Europe. An empirical study of applied corporate income taxation for SMEs compared to large enterprises, commissioned by the European Commission, May 2015.

Warda, J. (2001), 'Measuring the Value of R&D Tax Treatment in OECD Countries', STI Review No. 27: Special Issue on New Science and Technology Indicators, OECD Publishing.

Weber, T. O., Fooken, J. and Herrmann, B. (2014), 'Behavioural Economics and Taxation', Taxation paper, No 41, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Weiner, J. M. (2005), 'Formulary Apportionment and Group Taxation in the EU: Insights from the United States and Canada', Taxation Papers, Working Paper, No 8, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Weiner, J. M. (2006), 'Company Tax reform in the European Union: Guidance from the United States and Canada on Implementing Formulary Apportionment in the EU'. Springer Science, New York.

Zangari, E. (2014), 'Addressing the Debt Bias: A Comparison between the Belgian and the Italian ACE Systems', Taxation Papers, No 44, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

ZEW (2008), 'Study on the impact of reforms of corporate income taxation systems at the EU level on the size of the tax bases of the EU companies, using the model “European Tax Analyzer”, Final Report, Project for the EU Commission TAXUD/2007/DE/325.

ZEW (2015), 'Effective tax rates in an enlarged European Union' – Intermediate Report 2015, Project for the European Commission, TAXUD/2013/CC/120.

ZEW (2016a), 'The Effects of Tax Reforms to Address the Debt-equity Bias on the Cost of Capital and on Effective Tax Rates', forthcoming in Taxation Papers, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

ZEW (2016b), 'The Effect of Inflation and Interest Rates on Forward-looking Effective Tax Rates, forthcoming in Taxation Papers, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

ZEW (2016c), The Impact of Tax-planning on Forward-looking Effective Tax Rates, forthcoming in Taxation Papers, DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

  • 9. 
    A NNEXES Annex I: Procedural Information
  • 1. 
    L EAD DG, A GENDA P LANNING AND W ORK P ROGRAMME

The re-launch of a proposal for a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) was prepared under the lead of Directorate General for Taxation and Customs Union. Within the Agenda Planning of the European Commission, the project is referred to under item 2016/TAXUD/006. In the Commission Work Programme for 2016, the Commission committed under the header "Deeper and Fairer Internal Market with a Strengthened Industrial Base" to propose a staged approach starting with agreeing a mandatory tax base.

  • 2. 
    O RGANISATION AND T IMING

Work on the re-launch of the CCCTB started in July 2015.

An Inter-services Steering Group assisted DG Taxation and Customs Union in the preparation of this Impact Assessment report. The Steering Group was set up on 24/08/2015 and included colleagues from DG Communication Networks, Content and Technology; DG Competition; DG Economic and Financial Affairs; DG Environment; DG Financial Stability, Financial Services and Capital Markets Union; DG Internal Market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs; DG Justice and Consumers; DG Research and Innovation; DG Taxation and Customs Union; DG Trade; the Joint Research Centre; the Legal Service; and the Secretariat-General.

The Steering Group met on four occasions between September 2015 and June 2016. The last meeting of the Steering Group took place on 13 June 2016. At each occasion, the members of the Steering Group were given the opportunity to provide comments in writing on the draft versions of the documents presented.

  • 3. 
    C ONSULTATION OF THE R EGULATORY S CRUTINY B OARD

The impact assessment report was reviewed by the Regulatory Scrutiny Board on 20 th

July 2016. Based on the Board's recommendations, the impact assessment has been revised in accordance with the following points.

(1) The introduction (Section 1) has been amended to clarify and better explain the policy context. The other sections have been revisited to ensure consistency with the new introduction. A box on the 2011 proposal has been introduced in Section 1.

(2) The intervention logic was refined and is explained in Section 3 which now also includes a table which provides an overview of the links between problems, objectives and policy options as well as the general context. The choice of the preferred option for the scope has been elaborated more vis-à-vis the summary table 8.

(3) Throughout the text the references to baseline scenario have been clarified and streamlined to better explain the assessment of options. A new section on EU value added has been introduced in Section 2.5.

(4) Options have been numbered and further clarified with regard to the 2011 proposal. More information on the fiscal impact of the options has been added in the subsections of Section 5 and in annexes XII and XIII. . Section 5.5 has been expanded to explain better the implications of a staged approach.

(5) The REFIT elements have been added in Section 5.8 in the discussion of the preferred policy option.

  • 4. 
    E XTERNAL E XPERTISE

DG Taxation and Customs Union used external expertise to substantiate the discussion of the design of the CCCTB with extensive quantitative analysis. These projects were not triggered specifically by the decision to propose a re-launch of the CCCTB itself, but part of continuous analysis of policy issues in the area of corporate income taxation by DG TAXUD.

On the basis of administrative agreement between DG Taxation and Customs Union and

the Joint Research Centre (JRC) 110 , the JRC Institute for Prospective Technological

Studies (IPTS) has provided modelling support in the area of corporate tax policy. By means of econometric analysis and computable general equilibrium model, IPTS has analysed corporate income tax policy development and reforms.

Within the Framework Service Agreement with the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) on the "Provision of effective tax rates in the context of an enlarged

European Union and related supporting services" 111 , DG TAXUD signed specific

contracts for the analysis of effective tax rates. One of these studies explored potential effects of aggressive tax planning on the effective marginal and effective average

corporate tax rate of multinational corporations 112 . In another study, the ZEW analysed

the "The Effects of Tax Reforms to Address the Debt Bias on the Cost of Capital and on Effective Tax Rates".

For the studies prepared by the JRC and the ZEW, Annex 4 provides more detailed information on the model structure used, underlying assumptions and sensitivity of results.

In addition to these specific studies commissioned by DG TAXUD, there exist a number of other recent external studies of particular relevance for the design of a CCCTB. A list of the scientific papers referred to in the Impact Assessment is provided in Section 8 of the Impact Assessment report.

110 "Competitiveness and welfare effects of corporate tax reforms (TAXMOD-Corporate)", Administrative Agreement JRC N°33829 - TAXUD/2014/DE/324

111 Framework Service Contract TAXUD/2013/CC/120

112 "The Impact of Tax Planning on Forward-Looking Effective Tax Rates".

Annex II: Stakeholder Consultation – Synopsis Report

  • 1. 
    I NTRODUCTION

On 17th June 2015 the Commission published an action plan for a Fairer and Efficient Corporate Tax System which proposed 5 key areas for action in the coming months (COM (2015) 302 i). The re-launch of the Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) proposal lies at the heart of the action plan. It is presented as an overarching objective which has the potential to be an extremely effective tool for meeting the twin objectives of fairer and more efficient taxation.

The Inception Impact Assessment has been published on the EUROPA webpage early in the process to inform the public of the setup and scope of the re-launch of the CCCTB. The Commission has not received any direct feedback on this Inception Impact Assessment.

The Commission has furthermore run an open public consultation to consult all stakeholders and offer interested parties the possibility to provide their input to the relaunch of the CCCTB. 175 participants participated in this consultation.

The percentages given in this factual summary correspond to the responses submitted by stakeholders to the open public consultation. Beyond a statistical analysis of the data, the summary also provides a qualitative assessment of the valued opinions and input received.

  • 2. 
    B REAKDOWN OF P ARTICIPANTS

The majority of respondents were trade or business associations and companies (42% and 32% of responses, respectively). A comparably high share of responses came from Bulgarian companies (about 20%). The second largest group of responses came from trade/business associations in Belgium (some being representations to the EU). Respondents indicating "Other country" were located in Norway, Russia, South Africa, USA – or did not want to single out a specific country when their association or company group is located in many different countries.

Table 18: Distribution of respondents

Countries Private Non registered Registered individuals associations Associations Companies NGOs Academics Public Authorities Others Grand Total

Austria 0% 0% 1% 3% 0% 0% 1% 0% 4%

Belgium 1% 0% 10% 1% 3% 0% 0% 2% 16%

Bulgaria 0% 1% 0% 19% 1% 0% 0% 0% 21%

Czech Republic 0% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1%

Denmark 1% 0% 1% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 2%

Estonia 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1% 0% 1%

Finland 0% 0% 0% 1% 1% 0% 0% 0% 2%

France 1% 1% 2% 2% 0% 0% 0% 1% 6%

Germany 3% 0% 5% 2% 1% 1% 1% 1% 14%

Hungary 0% 0% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1%

Ireland 0% 1% 2% 1% 0% 0% 0% 1% 4%

Italy 1% 1% 4% 1% 0% 1% 0% 0% 7%

Lithuania 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1% 0% 0% 1%

Luxembourg 0% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1%

Malta 0% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1%

Other country 1% 0% 3% 1% 1% 0% 0% 0% 6%

Portugal 0% 0% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1%

Romania 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1%

Spain 0% 0% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1%

Sweden 0% 0% 2% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 2%

The Netherlands 1% 0% 1% 0% 1% 1% 0% 0% 3%

United Kingdom 0% 1% 5% 0% 1% 0% 0% 0% 7%

Grand Total 7% 5% 37% 32% 10% 3% 2% 5% 100%

Source: European Commission (2016), own calculations based on 175 responses

With respect to the 55 responses provided by individual companies, the data shows that a majority (30 out of 55) of the responses were provided by micro, small and mediumsized companies. This indicates the relative high interest also of smaller companies in the re-launch of the CCCTB.

Table 19: Distribution of responses submitted by companies

Economic

Sectors 1 - 9 10 - 49 50 - 249 250 or more Grand Total

Construction 2% 0% 0% 2% 4%

Electricty, Gas,

Water Supply, ... 0% 0% 0% 7% 7%

Financial and Insurance Activities

(incl. fund management activities) 0% 0% 2% 0% 2%

Manufacturing 2% 4% 4% 15% 24%

Professional, scientific and technical activities

(incl. accounting, bookkeeping, auditing activities) 11% 2% 0% 2% 15%

Wholesale and Retail Trade 18% 0% 0% 0% 18%

Other 7% 0% 2% 5% 15%

Multiple sectors 2% 7% 2% 5% 16%

Grand Total 42% 13% 9% 36% 100%

Source: European Commission (2016), own calculations based on 55 responses by companies

Figure 9: Participation in the public consultation - by type of respondent

Source: European Commission (2016), own calculations based on 175 responses

Figure 10: Responses by extent of national/international activities of respondents

Source: European Commission (2016), own calculations based on 162 responses, i.e. responses not by private individuals

  • 3. 
    A NALYSIS OF RESPONSES

    3.1 Policy directions

The Commission believes that the CCCTB system can be an effective tool against aggressive tax planning and at the same time retain its attractiveness to the business. What are your views?

Figure 11: Views on CCCTB as effective tool against aggressive tax planning

Source: European Commission

Table 20: Views on CCCTB as effective tool against aggressive tax planning – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent Agree Neutral Don't agree Other

(1) Private individuals and

      non registered associations 59% 9% 18% 14%

(2) Registered Associations 14% 27% 19% 41%

(3) Company 43% 30% 18% 9%

of which: SMEs 54% 34% 11% 0%

 Large enterprises 20% 25% 30% 25%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 68% 14% 4% 14%

(5) Academics 40% 0% 60% 0%

Grand Total 38% 23% 17% 22%

Source: European Commission

A majority of participating private individuals and civil society organisations share the view that CCCTB can be an effective tool against aggressive tax planning while retaining its attractiveness to business. A number of respondents mentioned that a common set of rules for calculating the corporate tax base, accompanied by consolidation, would prevent profit shifting, provide greater transparency and align economic activity with taxation. This will also make the EU a more attractive place for foreign firms to invest in and make doing business easier.

Many companies also broadly agree with this objective. Respondents who don't agree argue that the CCCTB should be focussed on removing cross-border obstacles in order to reduce tax compliance costs.

Furthermore a large majority of respondents from NGOs, public authorities and other respondents shared the view that the CCCTB could be an effective anti-avoidance tool within the CCCTB zone. For arrangements involving third countries, or tax avoidance by multinationals headquartered outside the CCCTB, the prevailing opinion is that the OECD BEPS project outcomes will provide more targeted and global responses and that diverging from OECD/BEPS could leave EU business at a competitive disadvantage. Therefore the CCCTB ''should not go faster and further than the rest of the world in implementing BEPS recommendations''.

Some respondents had some concerns about the overall administrative burden that many new rules could place on business and the risk that shifting the focus towards aggressive tax planning may undermine the original purpose of the CCCTB, i.e. to support EU business and make the internal market more business friendly. Concerns have also been expressed about the risk that the interaction between the formulary approach followed by the CCCTB and the arm's length principle strengthened by the OECD BEPS project could potentially lead to double taxation.

The Commission envisages re-launching the CCCTB in a staged approach which will consist of 2 steps: Firstly, agreement on the tax base, secondly, moving on to consolidation. What are your views on the staged approach?

Figure 12: Views on Staged Approach

Source: European Commission

Table 21: Views on Staged Approach – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent In favour of the staged approach Neutral Against the staged approach Other

(1) Private individuals and 50% 5% 36% 9%

      non registered associations

(2) Registered Associations 20% 27% 17% 36%

(3) Company 46% 21% 21% 11%

of which: SMEs 60% 26% 14% 0%

 Large enterprises 20% 15% 35% 30%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 25% 7% 64% 4%

(5) Academics 40% 20% 20% 20%

Grand Total 34% 19% 29% 19%

Source: European Commission

Among the respondents to the public consultation, in general more respondents were in favour of the staged approach than against. For those in favour of a staged approach, consolidation is essential and its introduction should follow as quickly as possible without delay. Therefore the first stage should incorporate a procedural path towards the second stage and a clear timeframe/ commitment to move to consolidation should be introduced at the outset.

Only the group of NGOs, public authorities and other respondents was – with a big majority – in favour of introducing the CCCTB in one move. These respondents argued that delaying consolidation would create uncertainty and a risk of more tax competition.

Among the remaining respondents, some are concerned that there is little point in achieving a CCTB when there may be difficulty making further progress; a few are in principle against the concept of CCCTB; and a couple support implementing the CCTB as a stand-alone and not depending on consolidation.

It is a priority of the Commission to promote discussion in Council of certain BEPS-related international aspects of the common base before the re-launched CCCTB is proposed. The aim will be to arrive at consensus on how to implement certain OECD anti-BEPS best practice recommendations in a uniform fashion across the EU. The intention would be to create a common playing field in defending the single market against base erosion and profit shifting.

What are your views on agreeing on such a common approach?

Figure 13: Views on Common approach

Source: European Commission

Table 22: Views on Common approach – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent In favour of common approach Neutral Against common approach Don't know Other

(1) Private individuals and 77% 14% 5% 0% 5%

      non registered associations

(2) Registered Associations 42% 20% 9% 0% 28%

(3) Company 66% 13% 11% 2% 9%

of which: SMEs 74% 14% 9% 3% 0%

 Large enterprises 50% 10% 15% 0% 25%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 39% 7% 4% 0% 50%

(5) Academics 80% 20% 0% 0% 0%

Grand Total 55% 15% 8% 1% 22%

Source: European Commission

In the responses to the consultation, NGOs stated their views that OECD has fallen short of expectations and that it is now up to the EU to go beyond the BEPS recommendations in order to close the remaining tax loopholes and develop a solution to the widespread phenomenon of tax avoidance. Only one reply from civil society organisations showed opposition to a common approach to implementing OECD anti-BEPS best practice recommendations. Companies believe that it is crucial for multinational entities to have stability and legal certainty. Accordingly, if the proposals of the OECD BEPS action plan were to be implemented by EU Member States unilaterally without any harmonisation or coordination, the basic principles of the OECD BEPS action plan would be violated and the chances to achieve its aims would be severely harmed. Only a small percentage of this category's respondents are opposed to the Commission's approach.

There is a strong support from registered business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms for the common implementation of the OECD BEPS principles through the EU. However the majority believes that EU anti-BEPS measures should not go beyond the OECD recommendations in order to avoid competitive disadvantages for EU companies.

As to the timing and modalities, some proposed an anti-BEPS directive to be supplemented with a strong dispute resolution system, while others questioned whether the CCCTB would be an appropriate mechanism to implement anti-BEPS measures before the common tax base has been agreed. A few objected that applying a one size fits all approach to tax legislation within the EU does not take into account the needs of different Member States.

3.2 Scope of the CCCTB proposal

The Commission considers making the new proposal for a CCCTB obligatory for all EU companies which are part of a group. A group can be formed:

  • - 
    Between parent and subsidiary companies where there is a holding of more than 50% of the voting rights; and direct or indirect holding amounting to more than 75% of capital or more than 75% of the profit rights); or
  • - 
    Between a Head Office and its permanent establishment where a company has one or more permanent establishment in other Member States.

What are your views on making the proposal for a CCCTB obligatory for all EU companies which are part of a group?

Would you suggest a different approach to defining who should be required to use the CCCTB? If yes, please explain your suggestion briefly.

Figure 14: Views on making CCCTB mandatory

Source: European Commission

Table 23: Views on making CCCTB mandatory – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent In favour of Neutral Against Don't know Other

mandatory CCCTB mandatory CCCTB

(1) Private individuals and

      non registered associations 45% 0% 41% 0% 14%

(2) Registered Associations 11% 11% 52% 0% 27%

(3) Company 41% 23% 29% 5% 2%

of which: SMEs 51% 29% 14% 6% 0%

 Large enterprises 20% 15% 55% 5% 5%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 64% 7% 14% 4% 11%

(5) Academics 20% 20% 0% 20% 40%

Grand Total 34% 13% 35% 3% 15%

Source: European Commission

Respondents from NGOs, public authorities and other respondents advocate a mandatory CCCTB given that an optional one would allow companies to choose the more profitable system, hence creating new arbitrage opportunities. A substantial number of respondents consider that the co-existence of two systems, the domestic one and the CCCTB, could cause the Internal Market to deteriorate and therefore propose a broader scope for the CCCTB to include all companies with a taxable presence in the EU.

Companies' opinions appear to be more divided. 40% of them support the Commission proposal. On the other hand 30% of them are opposed to a mandatory CCCTB. Even among the supporters, the definition of "group" gives rise to different views. Some respondents propose to include only cross-border entities while others prefer a threshold based on the turnover of the company.

The majority of business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms do not support this approach. The divergent opinions expressed on this question include the following: "Making the system optional could create an incentive for EU governments to create a system that is superior to existing individual systems and to give businesses a practical alternative." "For governments an optional system entails the benefit of a gradual adoption by businesses, thereby ensuring a limited short term impact on corporate tax".

Business and professional associations expressed concern about the definition of group for which the system should be mandatory. Considering the difficulty of introducing the concept of group for jurisdictions that have very different legal accounting models, some proposed that the criteria for defining a group should be based on the accounting directive.

The Commission envisages providing the following option:

Companies which would not be subject to the mandatory CCCTB - because they do not fulfil the requirements of being part of a group - could still have the possibility to apply the rules of the system.

What are your views on offering non-qualifying companies the option to apply the rules?

Figure 15: Views on possibility of opt-in

Source: European Commission

Table 24: Views on possibility of opt-in – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent In favour of opt-in Neutral Against opt-in Don't know Other

(1) Private individuals and 55% 14% 5% 9% 18%

      non registered associations

(2) Registered Associations 63% 19% 3% 2% 14%

(3) Company 75% 18% 5% 0% 2%

of which: SMEs 63% 29% 6% 0% 3%

 Large enterprises 95% 0% 5% 0% 0%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 36% 14% 32% 7% 11%

(5) Academics 60% 20% 20% 0% 0%

Grand Total 61% 17% 9% 3% 10%

Source: European Commission

Overall, a clear majority of the respondents to the consultation supports the possibility that non-qualifying companies could opt for applying the common tax base.

Most enterprises and business/professional associations support optionality for all companies. There is some agreement that a system mandatory for qualifying companies should allow non-qualifying companies to opt in. Others believe that allowing some companies to opt in would undermine the level playing field the CCCTB wants to create and will distort the system, opening it up to possible abuses and tax planning.

3.3 Anti-avoidance elements

In view of recent developments, the CCCTB system should include more robust rules to defend itself against aggressive tax planning.

Which of the elements of the CCCTB system would you reinforce so that the system can better respond to tax avoidance?

(Multiple answers possible)

Figure 16: Views on options to fight aggressive tax planning

Source: European Commission

Table 25: Views on options to fight aggressive tax planning – by type of respondent

Disallowance of tax

Type of Respondent Limiting Interest Deductibility exemption for portfolio Exit taxation rules More robust rules on CFC

participants

(1) Private individuals and

      non registered associations 27% 27% 41% 36%

(2) Registered Associations 2% 8% 6% 20%

(3) Company 4% 4% 20% 30%

of which: SMEs 0% 6% 26% 34%

 Large enterprises 10% 0% 10% 20%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 75% 68% 75% 75%

(5) Academics 40% 20% 60% 40%

Grand Total 18% 19% 27% 35%

Anti-abuse rules based Addressing distortions Type of Respondent on effective rather than casued by debt/equity Other suggestions None of the above

statutory rates bias

(1) Private individuals and 36% 41% 23% 18%

      non registered associations

(2) Registered Associations 6% 11% 72% 27%

(3) Company 41% 18% 16% 21%

of which: SMEs 57% 26% 3% 9%

 Large enterprises 10% 5% 40% 45%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 64% 68% 61% 0%

(5) Academics 20% 40% 60% 20%

Grand Total 31% 27% 46% 19%

Source: European Commission

All measures have received a certain support but, overall, there is a general demand for more robust CFC rules. In particular, many NGOs call for "full-inclusion" CFC rules which means: " treating all foreign affiliates of EU resident parent companies as CFCs so that the group consolidated profits are subject to tax in the resident country, with a full credit for all equivalent foreign taxes paid, which under the CCCTB should be apportioned among the group’s EU affiliates by an appropriate formula. This would protect the tax base of both source and residence countries. They should certainly not be limited to income from transactions with the parent company, and there should be no exemptions based on criteria such as effective exchange of information, as profits may also be shifted into cooperative jurisdictions. Full-inclusion CFC rules would be easier to apply than attempting to distinguish between active and passive income, or using a threshold such as 40% of the taxpayer’s effective tax rate."

Most of civil society respondents who chose 'other suggestion', argue that consolidation and harmonisation would make the listed elements unnecessary.

From the companies' perspective, improving arbitration seems to be essential.

The most recurrent 'other suggestion' from business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms include:

• a double tax avoidance mechanism (arbitration) between EU and non-EU country with a mandatory system for the EU through a directive;

• consistency between the anti-avoidance measures incorporated in the CCCTB and those advocated by the OECD;

• coordination with non-EU countries to avoid relocation of business activities outside the EU.

One respondent's comments summarise the prevailing opinion of this category: "Effective anti-avoidance rules are necessary under a CCCTB but they should not trigger any unintended consequences such as having a negative effect on investments into the EU or the international competitiveness of EU based groups".

3.4 Hybrid Mismatches

Hybrid mismatches are the result of disparities in the tax treatment of an entity or financial instrument under the laws of two or more States. Currently, arrangements can be set up to exploit such mismatches for the purpose of lowering their overall tax burden. The risk of such arrangements would be removed in transactions between enterprises applying the common tax base rules within a consolidated group. It would however persist in relations with enterprises outside the common rules as well as during step 1 of the staged approach to a CCCTB, in the absence of tax consolidation amongst the companies applying the common rules.

One option to address hybrid mismatches would be to require enterprises to follow in a Member State the classification of entities and/or of financial instruments adopted in the other Member State or the third country which is party to the transaction.

In your view, can hybrid mismatches be effectively addressed through any other measures than the one suggested above?

Figure 17: Views on whether hybrid mismatches can effectively be addressed through other measures

Source: European Commission

Table 26: Views on whether hybrid mismatches can effectively be addressed through other measures – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent Yes No Don't know Other

(1) Private individuals and

      non registered associations 32% 14% 32% 23%

(2) Registered Associations 20% 6% 25% 48%

(3) Company 13% 7% 61% 20%

of which: SMEs 11% 6% 83% 0%

 Large enterprises 15% 5% 25% 55%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 64% 0% 14% 21%

(5) Academics 20% 20% 20% 40%

Grand Total 26% 7% 35% 31%

Source: European Commission

The majority of NGOs and public authorities propose full-inclusion CFC rules as a key element to catch hybrids, accompanied by a credit for taxes paid abroad. One third doesn't know. A few suggest a public country by country report as an effective measure to cover more hybrid mismatches, others stress that consolidation would solve the discrepancies.

A vast majority of companies answered that they don't know, mainly driven by the responses of small and medium size enterprises. Only a few respondents, including multinationals, mentioned that hybrids could be avoided through OECD anti-BEPS actions.

Among registered business associations, some believe that the EU should not diverge from the OECD recommendations on this topic. Some make a distinction between intra EU situations, where a consolidated CCCTB from the beginning could solve the issue, and extra-EU situations where OECD/BEPS covers the issue. A couple of respondents say that hybrid instruments are not necessarily a result of tax planning.

3.5 Research and Development (R&D)

In the currently pending CCCTB proposal, the Commission has proposed a favourable treatment of costs for Research and Development (R&D) by making these costs fully deductible in the tax year they are incurred, with the exception of costs relating to immovable property. What are your views on the existing framework for R&D?

Figure 18: Views on existing R&D framework

Source: European Commission

Table 27: Views on existing R&D framework – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent In favour of the existing Neutral Against the existing Don't know Other

R&D framework R&D framework

(1) Private individuals and 55% 14% 9% 9% 14%

      non registered associations

(2) Registered Associations 59% 17% 5% 8% 11%

(3) Company 80% 5% 7% 0% 7%

of which: SMEs 83% 6% 9% 0% 3%

 Large enterprises 75% 5% 5% 0% 15%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 36% 7% 25% 0% 32%

(5) Academics 40% 20% 0% 0% 40%

Grand Total 61% 11% 9% 4% 14%

Source: European Commission

A large majority of respondents expressed strong support for the existing framework.

Many among the responding NGOs, public authorities and other respondents replied "other", mainly calling for clear definitions. It was also remarked that deduction of R&D costs should be strictly limited to genuine research and development costs in order to subsidise only real innovation.

The overwhelming majority of companies believe it is important to allow deduction of R&D and support the existing framework.

60% of respondents from registered business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms also support the existing framework. 17% are neutral, and a small number don't know. The other respondents from this category mostly ask for a clear definition of R&D, possibly consistent with the accounting definitions, or believe that "Member States should have flexibility to design tax policy for R&D within the BEPS work in order for the EU to remain attractive compared to extra-EU".

One option for rendering the CCCTB more favourable to promoting R&D could be to introduce more generous provisions for deducting R&D costs, such as super deductions which are currently applied by a number of Member States (e.g. Croatia, the Netherlands and the UK)? What are your views on making the existing framework for R&D more favourable? Would you suggest an alternative scheme? If so, please explain in your response and/or provide further comments

Figure 19: Views on possible improvements to the existing R&D framework

Source: European Commission

Table 28: Views on possible improvements to the existing R&D framework

– by type of respondent

In favour of Against improvements

Type of Respondent improvements to the Neutral to the existing R&D Don't know Other

existing R&D framework framework

(1) Private individuals and

      non registered associations 27% 18% 36% 5% 14%

(2) Registered Associations 50% 20% 3% 8% 19%

(3) Company 88% 7% 2% 2% 2%

of which: SMEs 80% 11% 3% 3% 3%

 Large enterprises 100% 0% 0% 0% 0%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 25% 0% 71% 4% 0%

(5) Academics 60% 0% 20% 0% 20%

Grand Total 55% 12% 18% 5% 10%

Source: European Commission

Most of the NGOs, public authorities are against R&D incentives for the reason that they can be used for aggressive tax planning. They argue that there are other means to stimulate R&D without risking new abuses. Some of them point out the lack of clear definitions. Some respondents would like to go further and reverse intellectual property regimes such as patent boxes.

With a completely different approach, almost all companies would welcome a more favourable framework for R&D as it would foster the economy.

Half of the respondents from business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms are in favour of making the existing framework for R&D more favourable. Their suggestions include:

• Super deductions (mostly); • Introduction of a common incentive rule such as an incremental deduction for R&D or an EU Intellectual Property box; • Tax credits (cash premiums) because super deductions tend to most benefit companies that are profitable; • Above-the-line R&D expenditure credits in EU countries so that even lossmaking companies can benefit from them.

Some respondents from this category believe that any EU initiative needs to build on the recent work of OECD and/or that Member States should be allowed to retain their flexibility in designing their own national R&D policies.

3.6 Debt equity bias

Corporate tax systems usually favour debt-financing over equity-financing by treating interest payments as a tax deductible expense with no equivalent deduction for the return paid to equity. Should debt bias be addressed in the proposal?

Figure 20: Views on whether debt bias should be addressed

Source: European Commission

Table 29: Views on whether debt bias should be addressed – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent Yes, debt bias should be addressed Neutral No, debt bias should not be addressed Don't know Other

(1) Private individuals and 55% 18% 14% 9% 5%

      non registered associations

(2) Registered Associations 28% 19% 14% 6% 33%

(3) Company 63% 13% 14% 9% 2%

of which: SMEs 63% 11% 11% 14% 0%

 Large enterprises 60% 15% 20% 0% 5%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 36% 32% 11% 7% 14%

(5) Academics 40% 40% 0% 20% 0%

Grand Total 44% 19% 13% 8% 15%

Source: European Commission

44% of respondents agree that the debt bias shall be addressed against 13.1% who think it should not. The 'yes' surpasses the 'no' in all categories of respondents, even though a large share of business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms chose the category 'other'. The majority of those who agree with addressing the debt bias stress distortions of economic decisions, notably related to investment.

Those among business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms who believe that debt/equity bias should not be addressed as part of the CCCTB argue that the CCCTB is primarily focused on the taxation of corporate groups and/or OECD/BEPS Action 4 recommendations need to be put in place and tested before considering a new set of rules.

Some argue that equity and debt are two different instruments with different rights and different costs and, as such, the tax treatment should not necessarily be the same and that a different treatment is justified for the banking sector. A couple think that a detailed assessment of the budgetary impact for each Member State is a pre-requisite; others suggest that since equity financing is not readily available in the EU any changes should not further impact the financing options available in the EU. A few respondents from this category replied in a completely positive manner.

The corporate tax debt equity bias could be addressed via three possible policy options.

Option 1 is the Comprehensive Business Income Tax (CBIT) that disallows any financing costs as deductible expense.

Option 2 is the Allowance for Corporate Equity (ACE) that allows the deductibility of actual interest payments and of a notional interest on equity.

Option 3 is the Cost of capital Allowance (CoCA) that allows the deductibility of a notional interest on capital (equity and debt).

In your view, which option would be best suited to address the corporate debt bias?

Figure 21: Views on options to address corporate tax debt equity bias

Source: European Commission

Table 30: Views on options to address corporate tax debt equity bias – by type of respondent

Comprehensive Business Allowance for Corporate Cost of Capital Type of Respondent None of the above Don't know Other

Income Tax (CBIT) Equity (ACE) Allowance (CoCA)

(1) Private individuals and 21% 32% 5% 16% 21% 5%

non registered associations

(2) Registered Associations 0% 50% 2% 12% 14% 22%

(3) Company 4% 52% 5% 11% 29% 0%

of which: SMEs 6% 31% 9% 11% 43% 0%

Large enterprises 0% 90% 0% 10% 0% 0%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 52% 15% 0% 11% 0% 22%

(5) Academics 0% 50% 0% 25% 25% 0%

Grand Total 12% 43% 3% 12% 18% 12%

Source: European Commission

More than 40% of the respondents favour an ACE system against 12% in favour of the CBIT and 3% in favour of the CoCA. 18% do not know, 12% want no solution and 11.4% want something other than the ones proposed.

Most of the NGOs opt for the CBIT method whereas from the companies' perspective there is resounding support for ACE. Several of those who support ACE argue that interest limitation shall be limited to OECD BEPS Action 4 and ask whether the proposal is in line with OECD BEPS Action 4. Like the companies, a strong majority of business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms expressed its preference for ACE. Some warn against the risk of raising tax rates and levelling down of deductibility of interest to pay for ACE.

3.7 Temporary mechanism for cross-border loss relief

The Commission envisages proposing a temporary mechanism for cross-border loss relief with recapture until the consolidation step (CCCTB) is agreed. The aim will be to balance out the absence of the benefits of consolidation during the first step (CCTB) of the proposal. What are your views on such a temporary mechanism for cross-border loss relief?

Figure 22: Views on temporary cross-border loss relief

Source: European Commission

Table 31: Views on temporary cross-border loss relief – by type of respondent

Type of Respondent In favour of a temporary Neutral Against a temporary Don't know Other

cross-border loss relief cross-border loss relief

(1) Private individuals and

      non registered associations 41% 14% 32% 5% 9%

(2) Registered Associations 52% 9% 3% 8% 28%

(3) Company 55% 25% 9% 5% 5%

of which: SMEs 54% 29% 9% 9% 0%

 Large enterprises 55% 20% 10% 0% 15%

(4) NGOs, Public authorities, Others 4% 14% 71% 0% 11%

(5) Academics 80% 0% 20% 0% 0%

Grand Total 45% 15% 20% 5% 15%

Source: European Commission

The majority of the companies who responded argue that the lack of mechanisms available to offset cross border losses is currently one of the major obstacles to the completion of the single market and reduces the competitiveness of EU. In addition, a few respondents suggest that the cross-border loss offset should be extended to non-EU companies and permanent establishments, given that competitiveness of EU companies needs to be regarded on a global scale.

In addition a strong majority of respondents from business/professional associations and consultancy/law firms also believe that consolidation is essential. However, they would accept a transitory and temporary cross-border loss relief as a second best approach. Some envisage resistance from Member States in offering wide-ranging cross-border relief as taxes should be paid where value is created. Others advocate the introduction of an EU wide regime, not linked to the CCCTB, to be implemented into domestic legislation.

Conversely most NGOs and civil society organizations don't support the introduction of a temporary mechanism for cross-border loss relief. They believe that postponing consolidation indefinitely while introducing a cross-border loss relief risks removing the main benefit of the proposal, while shrinking the taxable base of multinational companies and opening up the system to new types of aggressive tax planning.

3.8 Additional information provided by respondents

Is there anything else you would like to bring to the attention of the Commission?

The Commission services have analysed and factored into the summary all additional comments and papers that were submitted.

Annex III: Who is affected by the initiative and how

The objective of this annex is to set out the practical implications of the initiative for different types of companies and for national tax administrations.

The initiative directly affects companies falling under the mandatory scope, companies that are given the possibility to opt for the CCCTB and tax administrations. In a first step, all companies active in the EU would have to determine whether they fall under the mandatory application, depending on the threshold on consolidated turnover.

Large companies above the high turnover threshold that are subject to mandatory application of the CCCTB would be faced with new rules to compute the tax base in the Member States in which they are active, including the rules on consolidation and formula apportionment. This would inter alia entail a one-off cost for switching to new rules on (i) depreciation, (ii) the valuation of assets and liabilities, and (iii) the deductibility of expenses and exempt revenues, and for determining (iv) which parts of a group fall under the CCCTB definition of a group (and consolidating the EU-wide tax base for this group) and (v) the information required on the formula apportionment factors (assets, employment and wage bill, sales by destination) for each group member.

It is estimated that a vast majority of companies under the mandatory scope would be active cross-border (at least 80% for a threshold of EUR 750 million; at least 75% for a threshold of EUR 500 million, see table below). For companies active in several EU Member States, it is expected that the recurrent compliance costs will decrease considerably. The same is true for domestic companies that would wish to expand their operations to another EU Member State.

The fairly high turnover threshold envisaged under the preferred option would imply that only a small share of groups would be subject to mandatory application. By means of example, for a threshold of EUR 750 million the application would be compulsory for an estimated 1.6% of company groups the CCCTB. It is estimated that at most 19% of the groups subject to compulsory application are purely domestic groups.

SMEs and other companies which are not obliged to apply the CCCTB are free to stay within their national systems and would as such not be affected by the initiative. Those among these companies that consider the possibility to opt in would have to conduct a cost-benefit assessment to decide whether they would benefit from applying the CCCTB. Such cost-benefit analysis would also factor-in the costs for switching to the new system.

Tax administrations will also incur costs for implementing the new system, notably on IT and staff training. There will also be a need to coordinate in the EU the uniform implementation and practical application of the new rules. Eventually, tax administrations are expected to benefit from reduced dealings with transfer pricing issues and a reduced 'case number' to the extent that the tax affairs of a company group is mainly dealt with by the administration of the Member State where the parent resides.

Since the CCCTB would not be made mandatory for all firms, the burden for national administrations may overall go up slightly due to the required maintenance of two parallel systems.

Table 32: Estimated shares of groups, turnover and domestic groups for different size thresholds

Share of groups active only

Consolidated Share of groups, compared Corresponding share domestically compared to

turnover to total number of groups of unconsolidated turnover total number of groups in this

bracket 113

<= EUR 50 million 96.1% 19.9% 95.2%

> EUR 50 million 3.9% 81.1% 51.0%

> EUR 500 million 1.9% 68.6% 24.5%

> EUR 750 million 1.6% 64.2% 19.2%

Source: ORBIS and ORBIS Historical Ownership (December 2014)

113 This ratio has been computed for groups that have their Global Ultimate Owner (GUO) in the EU. In

other words, groups active in the EU but with GUO outside the EU are not reflected in this ratio. This

ratio therefore gives an upper estimate of the share of purely domestic groups.

Annex IV: Analytical Models used in preparing the Impact Assessment

  • 1. 
    CORTAX: A MODEL TO SIMULATE CORPORATE TAX POLICIES

1.1. Brief Description of the Model

The CORTAX model is a computable general equilibrium model designed to evaluate the effects of corporate tax reforms in 28 EU countries capturing the optimal behaviour of all agents in the economy. In the model, each country is assumed to have the same structure in terms of consumption, savings, production and public finances (though the data are country-specific). Countries are linked to each other via international trade in goods markets, international goods markets and investment by multinationals. The model also includes Japan, USA and a tax haven.

Firms are divided into three categories: multinationals headquarters, their subsidiaries located abroad and domestic firms that only produce in their country of residence. Multinationals and domestic firms differ to the extent that the former optimise profits globally and are engaged in profit shifting activities across borders. Domestic firms pay their corporate taxes in their country of residence according to the revenues generated in this country only. Both domestic and multinational firms shift profits to tax haven to reduce their tax burden. In the benchmark, all firms are equal and, whilst on aggregate taxable profits are positive, there are random shocks affecting their revenues that can be attributed to, for example, business cycle evolutions. These shocks may result in losses that can be carried forward in the model.

In relation to government, there is a balanced budget where consumption and public debt are a fixed proportion of GDP. Tax revenues and/or transfer payments adjust to keep a constant public budget. The taxes included in CORTAX are taxes consumption and direct taxes on income from corporate and labour, dividends, capital gains and interest. Government consumption and government debt as a share of GDP are maintained constant after a reform.

The effects of reforms can be expressed as changes in GDP, household consumption, business investment and fiscal revenue. The model is elaborated using data from different data sources including Eurostat, the OECD, the United Nations, the IMF and the Orbis firm database (see Section 4.2 below for more details). In the present exercise, the model has been constructed with a database for the year 2012. The structural description of the model and the calibration process borrow heavily from Bettendorf et al. (2009b).

1.2. Model Validation and Peer Review

The CORTAX model has acquired a strong reputation among corporate tax experts. As noted, the model was originally produced by CPB Netherlands, and has since been used by experts affiliated to the Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation, the Erasmus University Rotterdam, the Tinbergen Institute and CESifo. The model was previously used in an Impact Assessment (European Commission, 2011a), which drew extensively from a report produced for DG TAXUD (Bettendorf et al., 2009b). Among other policies, the report analysed both a common corporate tax base and a common consolidated corporate tax base for the EU.

The CORTAX model has been the basis for a number of publications in peer-reviewed journals. Of particular note is Bettendorf et al. (2010a) in Economic Policy which simulates a common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) across the EU, with further innovations of the ideas subsequently published in Fiscal Studies (Bettendorf et al., 2010b). The issue of using CORTAX to analyse the debt bias in corporate taxation was addressed in de Mooij and Devereux (2011b) published in International Tax and Public Finance. An earlier publication in The World Economy used CORTAX to analyse the impact of corporate taxation on the labour market (Bettendorf et al., 2009a). That the model has stood up to the rigorous standards required to be accepted by journals of this quality reflects the level of the theoretical and empirical work underlying the model, and that it is appropriate for analysing key policy questions in the area of corporate taxation.

1.3. Discussions with External Experts

As noted in the previous section, the CORTAX model has been accepted within the corporate taxation community for some years. The model has been used by leading research institutes and universities, and work based around the model has been accepted for publication in high-level, peer-reviewed academic journals in the area of fiscal policy.

Since this earlier body of work, the model data has been updated by the Tax Modelling Group in JRC-Seville. This extensive recalibration process has been carried out in conjunction with external experts, as appropriate. The team has collaborated closely with Leon Bettendorf (CPB Netherlands), one of the original authors of the model, and lead author for many of the reports and journal articles. Regarding the calibration, the team has worked with Simon Loretz (Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna), who produced much of the data for the previous calibration of the model during his time at the Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation, and was a co-author for the report that formed the basis of the 2011 Impact Assessment (European Commission, 2011a).

1.4. Underlying Assumptions and Data Input

1.4.1 Baseline and key assumptions

In CORTAX, we account for two types of households: old and young. Their lifetime is 40-year periods each and their behaviour remains the same during the whole period. Households maximise their intra-temporal utility function subject to a budget constraint, where net savings from young workers (wages, current transfers and negative consumption) are equal to negative value of net savings from old households. The effects on welfare are calculated using the compensating variation. This is calculated as the difference in transfers received by young households required to compensate the change in utility.

Firms maximise their value subject to the production function and the accumulation constraints on physical capital and fiscal depreciation. Total production is calculated as the sum of production in all firms (domestic and multinationals) net of intermediate inputs in foreign subsidiaries. Usually, the production function is a Cobb Douglas combination of the fixed factor and the value added, which is a CES aggregate of labour and capital. The model allows the parent company to charge a transfer price for intra-firm deliveries that deviates from the equivalent price that would be charged if it had been an inter-firm transaction (the ‘arms-length’ price), which reflects profit shifting in multinationals. In the case of domestic firms, these practices are captured with the existence of a tax haven. Profit shifting to tax havens depends on the difference between the statutory rate in their respective countries and the tax rate in the tax haven.

The simulations are coded to ensure that the government budget remains balanced. This is achieved in two ways. First, it is assumed that governments will adjust the corporate tax rates to maintain constant corporate tax revenue, prior to any behavioural response (i.e. ex-ante to the simulation). Any revenue changes due to the behavioural responses (i.e. ex-post to the simulation) are accounted for by the government adjusting transfers to retirees.

1.4.2 Key sources of macroeconomic and socio-economic data

The current calibration largely uses the same data sources as the original calibration of CORTAX as outlined in Bettendorf and van der Horst (2006), though in a few cases alternatives were used if these were considered more reliable, or the original source was no longer available. The year 2012 was chosen as reference year for the calibration, as it represented a good compromise between timeliness and completeness. The countries covered are the 28 EU member states, the United States and Japan.

Population and employment statistics come from the United Nations and national accounts data on income and expenditure are collected from OECD and Eurostat. Purchasing power parity (PPPs) exchange rates are from the IMF and Eurostat and general government consolidated gross debt as a percentage of GDP is from DG ECFIN’s Ameco Database. Additionally, CORTAX needs bilateral FDI positions as part of the calibration. For these, the modelling starts with the Eurostat bilateral positions. Data on Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) flows by country of origin and country of receipt are from Eurostat (financial account, direct investment, reporting economy). As a number of countries have incomplete information on the country of origin of the inward FDI stock, the modellers impute these values following the practice in Bettendorf and van der Horst (2006), and a correction is made when the FDI data represent special purpose entity activity.

Finally, CIT receipts as a percentage of GDP are from European and the OECD while information on balance sheets and ownership structure are extracted from the Orbis database, provided by Bureau Van Dijk. Although Orbis is a firm-level database, for the purposes of the calibration it is only used to produce national-level estimates of debt shares and of corporate investment shares (by type of asset) so as to calculate relevant corporate tax parameters such as the cost of capital (financed via equity or debt).

1.4.3 Construction of the baseline and core policy simulations

The data described above is entered into the model, which provides a consistent and connected framework for firms, household and governments. The data and the current policies of each country are used to replicate the corporate taxation regime, and indeed the production structure and household behaviour. The corporate taxation regime is necessarily stylised (for example, not every deduction can be included), though the simulations confirm that at a macro-level the CIT regimes are replicated well.

The core simulations have been chosen to reflect potential policy options for harmonisation of corporate tax bases in the EU. Following the proposal (European Commission, 2015a), two main reforms are considered: the common corporate tax base (CCTB), and the common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB). Both reforms are assumed to be mandatory for multinationals only (though the work also simulates the case where domestic firms participate). The CCCTB proposal offers a holistic solution to profit shifting. It combines a common tax base together with consolidation of each multinational group's profit, removing the incentive to engage in profit shifting. Under this reform, the consolidated tax base must then be apportioned to each country according to an agreed formula. Both the CCTB and CCCTB require a definition of the common tax base, which according to our interpretation of the legislation is defined as follows: a 12.5 percent straight line depreciation rate for machinery (8 years), a 4 percent rate for industrial buildings (25 years), a 6.67 percent rate for intangibles (15 years) and an average value for inventories (alternative tax bases are also simulated as part of the sensitivity analysis).

Debt and equity financing can be seen as imperfect substitute forms of capital use, and their different tax treatment introduces an obvious distortion in the way firms and investors choose to invest funds – the so-called debt bias. The main proposals to correct for this tax-induced debt bias are, first, the comprehensive business income tax (CBIT), which fully disallows the deductibility of interest, and so taxes all returns to investment including the "normal" return. Second, an allowance for corporate capital (ACC) provides an imputed return to investment, regardless of its form (debt or equity). Third, an allowance for corporate equity (ACE/AGI, undistinguished in the model) keeps the deductibility of interest (like in the traditional corporate tax design), but adds a deductible imputed return for equity investments. All these are introduced by changing how the corporate tax base is calculated. The change in tax liability has implications for the cost of capital, and hence for investment decisions.

1.4.4 Sensitivity of model results and likely robustness to changes in the underlying assumptions and/or data input

Extensive sensitivity analysis has been conducted around the core policy simulations. These simulations provide additional insights into the consequences of altering the model assumptions or policy choices, and offer a strong test of the robustness of the results. The eight types of sensitivity analysis are as follows: (i) implementing the common corporate (CCTB and CCCTB) for all firms, rather than just multinationals, (ii) alternative definitions of the common tax base, (iii) stricter control on profit shifting, (iv) alternative choices for capital-labour substitutability, (v) less compliance cost saving from consolidation, (vi) compensate revenue with labour taxes, instead of changing transfer payments, (vii) discrete location choice for firms, (viii) inclusion of a cross-border loss offset provision with the common corporate tax base (CCTB), (ix) alternative deductibility shares and rates for the ACE/AGI, and (x) alternative assumptions on the ex-ante CIT rate closure.

The sensitivity analysis provides a more rounded picture of the model. Where different model assumptions are simulated (such as alternative capital-labour substitutability or less compliance cost savings), some changes in the magnitude of the effects are observed, though the broad conclusions remain. For all core and sensitivity simulations full country-level results are provided, as are additional tables as necessary to explain the results.

  • 2. 
    E FFECTS OF FUNDAMENTAL TAX REFORMS ON EFFECTIVE TAXATION

2.1. Brief Description of the Model

Corporate tax systems in Europe usually encourage the use of debt rather than equity financing as interest payments are deductible for tax purposes while equity returns are not. This unequal treatment might cause economic problems, such as excessive leverage in the corporate sector and an associated increased vulnerability to economic crises. The report focuses on the current extent of the corporate debt bias in the tax systems of the EU-28 Member States and informs about whether different reform options could in principle manage to address the debt bias and promote investment, possibly in a revenue neutral way.

The report analyses current interest deduction limitation rules, intended to prevent an excessive use of debt financing, and assess the impact of interest deductions limitations rules on effective tax burdens in the EU-28 Member States. The main focus of the study is the analysis of the consequences of four fundamental tax reforms which try to overcome the debt bias differently, i.e. the Comprehensive Business Income Tax (CBIT), Allowance for Corporate Equity (ACE), Allowance for Corporate Capital (ACC), Cost of capital Allowance (CoCA).

The study relies on the general framework of the Devereux/Griffith model which provides different indicators of the effective tax burden levied on corporate investments. The Devereux/Griffith model allows considering marginal and profitable investments and different financing sources taking into account the taxes borne at the corporate level and the level of the shareholders. For marginal investments, the model provides the cost of capital and the effective marginal tax rate (EMTR) as a measure of effective taxation. The cost of capital represents the minimum pre-tax rate of return required for a real investment to achieve the same after-tax return as a safe investment in the capital market and should, from a theoretical point of view, impact on the scale of investments. For profitable investments, the effective average tax rate (EATR) is a more proper measure of the effective tax burden levied on the investment return and is used to identify the effect of taxation on discrete location choices.

The fundamental reform options will impact the tax bases at corporate and shareholder level differently and, therefore, will affect Member States tax revenues. Member States might be reluctant to suffer revenue losses or increase their statutory tax rates as this is associated with lower investment rates and growth. The report provides options for a revenue neutral introduction of the fundamental tax reforms as well as possible consequences for the level of investment in the EU-28 Member States.

2.2. Model validation and peer review

The Devereux and Griffith methodology has acquired a strong reputation among corporate tax experts. This approach is rooted in the model originally proposed by King and Fullerton (1984) and as such has the advantage of allowing the computation of both effective marginal tax rate and effective average tax rate under a unique framework.

The EMTR method has been extensively used to compute the effective tax rates levied on capital income from different domestic investment over time and across countries. However, as Devereux and Griffith (1998) demonstrate, this indicator may not be a suitable one when the purpose of the analysis is the international location of capital. In these circumstances, firms usually face a choice between two or more mutually exclusive investment projects that are expected to earn some economic rent. The location choice will be made on the basis of the highest post-tax economic rent, that is to say, where the proportion of total income taken in taxes is the lowest. The most suitable measure for a highly profitable multinational to adopt when deciding where to invest is the EATR, that is, the present value of the expected total tax burden in relation to total profits. The EATR is usually higher than the EMTR. The reason is that many tax deductions apply to the cost of investment projects (which for the marginal investment project are equal to the rate of return) but are irrelevant for economic rent. Once the strategic location choice has been made, the cost of capital and the EMTR play an important role in determining the optimal scale of the investment.

A range of studies have examined the theoretical foundation of the Devereux/ Griffith model and its scope of application (Lammers 2002; Schreiber et al. 2002; Devereux and Griffith, 2003). These forward-looking indicators permit to compare international tax regimes and to isolate the structure of incentives and disincentives given by the different tax systems to undertake a specific investment. Hence, these indicators are a useful policy tools in the analysis of the effects of corporate tax differentials on resource allocation.

The Devereux/Griffith approach was previously used in an Impact Assessment by the European Commission (EEC 2001), following the advice of a panel of academic experts, to comply with the mandate of the ECOFIN Council in December 1998 concerning the

scope of the analysis of effective tax rates. 114 Since then the methodology has been

applied for the calculation of effective tax rates in the EU and other countries on a yearly basis.

2.3. Underlying assumptions and data input

2.3.1. Baseline and key assumptions

To gain insights on the effects of different reform options on effective tax rates, the cost of capital and the EATR of the reform scenario are compared to the pre-reform scenario (status quo). The results for the effective tax rates for the year 2015 are used as the status quo scenario.

The basic approach proposed by Devereux and Griffith is to consider hypothetical incremental investment located in a specific country undertaken by a company resident possibly in the same country, but also possibly in another country. The hypothetical investment takes place in one period and generates a return in the next period. The impact of taxation is analysed by considering a number of features of the tax system, including the statutory tax rate, capital allowances, depreciation rules and the treatment of different financing sources, the treatment of foreign source income, wealth taxes paid by the company, as well as possibly the treatment at the corporate and personal level of

dividends paid by the company, and wealth and capital gains taxes. 115 The tax database

comprises all relevant tax parameters for the EU-28 Member States.

114 For a deeper analysis of the pros and cons of the forward-looking indicators for policy-makers, see

Giannini and Maggiulli (2002).

115

Both the cost of capital and the EATR are computed for five different types of assets (intangibles, buildings, machinery, financial assets, inventory), three different sources of financing (retained earnings, new equity, debt) and by three types of shareholders (zerorate, top-rate non-qualified and top-rate qualified) and can thereby be used to compare the relative distortions introduced by the tax system in relation to certain investments or financing sources both at the corporate level and shareholder level.

In presenting averages over different forms of assets, these assets are weighted equally, while unequal weights are used for financing: retained earnings 55%, new equity 10%, and debt 35% (OECD, 1991). As for true economic depreciation rates it is assumed in all countries: intangibles (15.35%), industrial buildings (3.1%); machinery (17.5%), financial assets (0%), and inventories (0%).

The alternative form of investment is assumed to be lending and the alternative investments earns a real interest rate of 5%. The inflation rate is assumed to be 2% in all countries. The computations of EATRs are based on a pre-tax rate of profitability of 20% which corresponds to the standard economic assumption.

2.3.2. Construction of the core policy impact assessment

The report provides calculation of effective tax rates using the Devereux/Griffith model for Member States with interest deduction limitation rules by assuming binding limits to the deductibility of interest costs.

Thin capitalization or earnings stripping rules limit the deductibility of interest costs in case of debt financing and can be found in more and more Member States. The Devereux/Griffith model does not allow a detailed implementation of interest deduction limitation rules. In previous reports on effective taxation in the European Union, it has always been assumed that interest costs were deductible irrespective of the existence of limitation rules. For the purpose of this study, it is assumed that the limitations with regard to interest costs are applicable. In Member States with interest deduction limitation rules, this will result in a complete non-deductibility of interest costs at the corporate level. The chosen approach (applicable vs. non-applicable) will neglect substantial differences in the existing interest limitation deduction rules of the Member States at the corporate level, like a possible carry-forward of non-deductible interest. Therefore, the report will interpret the results cautiously.

Moreover, for the analysis of fundamental tax reforms, the tax codes of Belgium and Italy are modified. Both Member States have already implemented one type of fundamental tax reform: the Allowance for Corporate Equity. For the analysis of the other hypothetical fundamental tax reforms, it is consistent to assume that no other fundamental tax reform is currently in place. Otherwise, the effects of two fundamental tax reforms (e.g. CBIT and ACE) would overlap and might even contradict and compensate each other.

2.3.3. Sensitivity of model results and likely robustness to changes in the underlying assumptions and/or data input

The effect of the revenue neutral fundamental tax reforms on the EATR might differ if the pre-tax rate of profitability is changed. Therefore, a sensitivity analysis with pre-tax rates of profitability below and above the base case assumption of 20% is conducted. The sensitivity of the effective tax measures to the assumed inflation and interest rates are discussed in ZEW (2016b).

  • 3. 
    T HE IMPACT OF TAX PLANNING ON FORWARD - LOOKING EFFECTIVE TAX RATES

3.1. Brief description of the model

Multinationals companies have the opportunity to apply profit shifting strategies to reduce their tax payments in high-tax countries and minimize the overall effective tax burden on their global profits. The tax planning strategies of multinational corporations have been a key issue on the international policy agenda for some years now. The aim of the report is to explore the implications of typical tax planning strategies on effective tax rates for cross-border investments between the 28 EU member states and the US.

The report derives forward-looking average and marginal effective tax rates that incorporate the possibility of sophisticated tax planning strategies by multinationals and the existence of preferential tax regimes such as IP boxes. Profit shifting channels from high-tax to low-tax countries cover intra-group debt shifting, royalty payments, as well as transfer pricing of goods and services. A number of cases are considered, including “triangular” structures involving the use of tax haven finance affiliates and the use of hybrid entities and hybrid instruments. The report also provides insights on the potential impact of anti-avoidance measures against so-called aggressive tax planning.

As in the annually updated report on effective tax rates conducted by ZEW, the study at hand applies the Devereux/Griffith model to calculate cost of capital (CoC) and effective average tax rates (EATR). This allows one to compare the results for different tax planning structures to the results for direct cross-border investments known from the annual updates.

3.2. Model validation and peer review

The Devereux and Griffith methodology has acquired a strong reputation among corporate tax experts. This approach is rooted in the model originally proposed by King and Fullerton (1984) and as such has the advantage of allowing the computation of both effective marginal tax rate and effective average tax rate under a unique framework.

The Devereux/ Griffith approach was previously used in an Impact Assessment by the European Commission (EEC 2001), following the advice of a panel of academic experts, to comply with the mandate of the ECOFIN Council in December 1998 concerning the

scope of the analysis of effective tax rates. 116 Since then the methodology has been

applied for the calculation of effective tax rates in the EU and other countries on a yearly basis.

A range of studies have examined the theoretical foundation of the Devereux/ Griffith model and its scope of application (Lammers 2002; Schreiber et al. 2002; Devereux et al. 2003). OECD (2007) provides specific considerations on cross-border METR/AETR

116 For a deeper analysis of the pros and cons of the forward-looking indicators for policy makers, see Giannini and Maggiulli (2002).

analysis with triangular financing structure. The issue of incorporating IP Box regimes into a model of effective tax rates was addressed in Evers et al. (2015).

3.3. Underlying assumptions and data input

3.3.1. Baseline and key assumptions

The basic framework underlying the Devereux/Griffith model for cross-border settings with a parent company and its subsidiary located in different countries have been established in several earlier studies undertaken by ZEW on behalf of the European Commission. The focus here is on multinational corporations hence the case of incorporated SMEs and partnerships is ignored. Given to the high mobility on the international capital market, personal taxes are of little importance for decision making in multinational enterprises. Therefore, the analysis is limited to the corporate level (i.e. excluding shareholders' taxation).

The basic approach proposed by Devereux and Griffith is to consider hypothetical incremental investment located in a specific country undertaken by a company resident possibly in the same country, but also possibly in another country. The hypothetical investment takes place in one period and generates a return in the next period. The impact of taxation is analysed by considering a number of features of the tax system, including the statutory tax rate, capital allowances, depreciation rules and the treatment of different financing sources, the treatment of foreign source income, wealth taxes paid by the company, as well as possibly the treatment at the corporate and personal level of

dividends paid by the company, and wealth and capital gains taxes. 117

Both the cost of capital and the EATR are computed for five different types of assets (intangibles, buildings, machinery, financial assets, inventory) and three different sources of financing (retained earnings, new equity, debt). In presenting averages over different forms of assets, these assets are weighted equally, while unequal weights are used for financing: retained earnings 55%, new equity 10%, and debt 35% (OECD, 1991). As for true economic depreciation rates it is assumed in all countries: intangibles (15.35%), industrial buildings (3.1%); machinery (17.5%), financial assets (0%), and inventories (0%).

The alternative form of investment is assumed to be lending and the alternative investments earns a real interest rate of 5%. The inflation rate is assumed to be 2% in all countries. The computations of EATRs are based on a pre-tax rate of profitability of 20% which corresponds to the standard economic assumption.

3.3.2. Construction of the core policy impact assessment

The report extends the basic formulas underlying the Devereux/Griffith model for crossborder settings - with a parent company and its subsidiary located in different countries - for implementing representative profit shifting strategies via interest and royalty payments. A number of cases are considered:

117 It is assumed that the tax system remains unchanged over the life of the investment.

(1) Tax planning via an intermediate financing company resident in a tax-exempt country which grants a loan to the subsidiary and receives the marginal return of the investment as interest.

(2) The second tax planning strategy replicates tax planning strategy 1 but assumes that the intermediate company is resident in a fictitious EU average country.

(3) Tax planning strategy 3 replicates tax planning strategy 1 but assume that the loan granted to the subsidiary has a hybrid element resulting in its classification as equity capital in the country of residence of the intermediate company.

(4) Tax planning strategy 4 replicates tax planning strategy 2 considering a hybrid loan.

(5) Under tax planning strategy 5 profits are not shifted via debt financing but via royalty payments. It is assumed that the subsidiary invests in a bundle of assets (buildings, machinery, inventory, and a financial asset) whereas the intangible asset used in the production process is owned by a separate intellectual property (IP) holding company resident in a tax-exempt country. The intangible is licensed to the subsidiary which generates profits from the use of the intangible and forwards these profits to the IP holding company in the form of a royalty payment.

(6) Tax planning strategy 6 replicates tax planning strategy 5 but assumes that the IP holding company is resident in the fictitious EU average country.

(7) Tax planning strategy 7 replicates tax planning strategy 5 but assumes that the IP holding company is resident in one of the EU member states offering an IP-box regime.

As for the tax-exempt country, two different assumptions are made: (i) "Offshore treaty" is assumed to be a non-EU tax exempt country that does not levy any kind of profit and non-profit taxes but has concluded tax treaties with all EU member states and the US reducing all withholding taxes to zero; (ii) "Offshore no treaty" is assumed to be a non EU tax exempt country that that does not levy any kind of profit and non-profit taxes and has not concluded tax treaties with all EU member states and the US, therefore domestic withholding tax rates apply (up to 75% in France). The fictitious EU average country is defined as an average EU member states. Relevant tax parameters for this country are the arithmetic means of the respective tax parameters across all 28 EU member states.

The calculations are based on tax law data for the year 2015 (ZEW 2015). The tax database comprises all relevant tax parameters for the EU-28 Member States. Additional tax parameters used in the study at hand include (i) withholding taxes on dividends, interest and royalties between EU and US companies; (ii) IP-box regimes in the EU member states.

3.3.3. Sensitivity of model results and likely robustness to changes in the

underlying assumptions and/or data input

The effect of the revenue neutral fundamental tax reforms on the EATR might differ if the pre-tax rate of profitability is changed. Therefore, a sensitivity analysis with pre-tax rates of profitability below and above the base case assumption of 20% is conducted (ZEW 2016c). The sensitivity of the effective tax measures to the assumed inflation and interest rates are discussed in ZEW (2016b).

Annex V: Formula apportionment

This annex presents the formula apportionment outlined in the 2011 impact assessment and proposal for a CCCTB. The approach of 2011 is furthermore complemented by findings in the literature since then.

  • 1. 
    I NTRODUCTION

The 2011 proposal for a CCCTB 118 is a system of common rules for computing the tax

base of companies which are tax resident in the EU and of branches of third-country companies located in the EU. Specifically, the common fiscal framework provides for rules to compute each company's (or branch's) individual tax results, the consolidation of those results, when there are other group members, and the apportionment of the consolidated tax base to each eligible Member State.

In the CCCTB, the consolidated tax base is apportioned to the different jurisdictions in which the group entities operate according to the formula set out in Articles 86-102 of the 2011 proposal for the CCCTB. The formula establishes a method to determine the respective economic presence and activity of subsidiaries in a particular geographic location ('allocation'), i.e. the taxable profit of a multinational entity within a specific jurisdiction. Generally, for the purpose of establishing a taxable presence, formulary systems apportion income with reference to inputs and outputs, which respectively reflect supply and demand components of income production. The formula attributes profits to those Member States where the economic activity takes place as measured by the factors in the formula.

Formula apportionment is a necessary consequence of consolidation. In this annex, the elements of the formula apportionment mechanism in the 2011 proposal of the CCCTB will be outlined. Section 2 of this annex describes the proposed CCCTB's apportionment formula and its allocation factors as defined in the Directive. Section 3 presents an overview of the steps which led to the emergence of formulary apportionment as the Commission's preferred allocation mechanism. Section 4 reviews the treatment of formula apportionment in the 2011 Impact Assessment which accompanied the CCCTB proposal, specifically with respect to the analysis and conclusions of three main studies: (i) PricewaterhouseCoopers (PwC) Study: (ii) Amadeus and Orbis database; and (iii) CORTAX study. Section 5, presents a brief review of literature on formula apportionment, leading up to and following the 2011 CCCTB proposal. Section 5 concludes.

  • 2. 
    A PPORTIONMENT F ORMULA IN THE 2011 CCCTB

Following on from the work of the CCCTB Working Group, the formula proposed by the Directive is based on company-specific data and comprises three equally weighted factors (labour, assets and sales):

  • i. 
    Labour is computed based on both payroll and the number of employees (each item counts for half);
  • ii. 
    Assets consist of all fixed tangible assets, meaning that intangibles and financial assets are excluded from the formula apportionment;

118 SEC(2011) 315-316.

  • iii. 
    Sales are taken into account to increase the taxing entitlement of the Member State of destination.

The choice of the three factors stems from the need to reflect both the state of production (supply side, measured by assets and/or labour payroll) and the state of demand (sales to destination) to describe economic activity properly. Specifically, the apportionment share of the consolidated tax base of a 'group member A' is determined by the following formula:

Share A = � 1 𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆

𝐴𝐴 𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴 𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴

3 𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 +

1 1

3 � 2 + 𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 +

1 𝑁𝑁𝑃𝑃 𝑃𝑃𝑜𝑜 𝑆𝑆𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴

2 𝑁𝑁𝑃𝑃 𝑃𝑃𝑜𝑜 𝑆𝑆𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 � +

1

3 𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 �

∗ 𝐶𝐶𝑃𝑃𝑛𝑛 ′ 𝑑𝑑 𝑇𝑇𝑆𝑆𝑇𝑇 𝐵𝐵𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆

Sales are weighted by one-third, payroll by one-sixth, the number of employees by onesixth, and assets by one-third. The sum of the weights equals one so that 100% of the CCCTB is apportioned across the Member States. Member States can then apply the national corporation tax rates to their respective shares of taxable bases.

Apportionment factors

The provisions of the proposed Directive that regulate the sharing mechanisms are contained in Article 86, which illustrates the general formula, up to Article 103, in which

the provisions deal with the three apportionment factors in detail. 119

In accordance with Articles 90 and 91, the labour factor is subdivided into two equally weighed components: payroll and number of employees as measured at the year end. Specifics regarding the definition of employee, the inclusion of seconded employees and temporary workers, as well as a broad definition of payroll and how it is allocated are also provided. The inclusion of the two components in the labour factor reflects the need to take into account cross-country disparities (due to the variance in labour productivity) across the EU.

Pursuant to Articles 92, 93, and 94, assets include all fixed tangible assets (owned, fixed, or rented), which are allocated to the economic owner or to the legal owner (in the event that the first is not identifiable), and are valuated according to defined valuation principles. Inventory, intangible and financial assets are excluded from the formula due to their mobile nature and the risks of circumventing the system. The computation of the asset factor includes all the costs incurred for research, development, marketing and advertising in the six year period preceding the entry into the CCCTB system. The use of the labour and asset factors gives appropriate weight to the interests of the Member State of origin.

Finally, sales are taken into account in order to ensure fair participation of the Member State of destination. The sales factor, defined in Article 95, consists of the proceeds from the total sale of goods and supplies of services of a group member. The definition excludes 'exempt revenues' and 'dividends' from the sales factor, as they respectively do not contribute to the tax base and have no readily identifiable geographic location. Intragroup sales of goods and supplies are excludable in accordance to the same principle, i.e., that a factor which does not contribute to the tax base should not be used to apportion the base. The sales factor is attributed to group members on a 'destination' basis, as it is

119 See CCCTB Arts 86-103.

designed to reflect the state of demand (sales to destination), and specific rules address situations in which the general rules might create 'nowhere' income.

In addition to the general rules, the CCCTB contains three provisions: the general antiabuse rule, the safeguard clause (applicable to apportionment) and an explicit grant of rulemaking authority to the Commission to calculate apportionment factors. The provisions provide an alternative method where the outcome of the apportionment does not fairly represent the extent of business activity. The provisions determine the composition of factors and the attribution of the tax base for specific industries. Specifically, the CCCTB proposal includes special apportionment rules for four industries: financial institutions; insurance undertakings; oil and gas; and transportation (shipping, inland waterway transport, and air transport). Insofar as certain aspects of formula apportionment could create planning opportunities, these provisions provide the basis for limiting their scope.

  • 3. 
    H OW THE SHARING MECHANISM WAS CHOSEN

The Commission's proposed sharing mechanism, or apportionment formula, has been the outcome of a comprehensive analysis. The Commission refined its ideas largely though the CCCTB Working Groups: formula apportionment was among the main building blocks of the CCCTB which was reviewed and analysed by the CCCTB WG and its subgroup

6 on the sharing mechanism. 120 The main findings are contained in various working papers, 121 analysing the main issues linked to valuation, location, availability of

data, advantages and disadvantages of the three factors of formula apportionment. In addition to the consultations of the working group, the Commission conferred with

academic experts on allocation mechanisms 122 and invited experts to evaluate the formula, commissioned a study, 123 published its own study, 124 and conducted an Impact Assessment 125 on its chosen three-factor formula which accompanied the proposal for a

Council Directive on a CCCTB.

As an outcome to this extensive analysis, stakeholder and experts in the field have agreed that the three-factor formula best fulfils the principles that have guided the design of the sharing mechanism, i.e. the formula should: (i) be as simple as possible for taxpayers and

120 A subgroup was set up in December 2004 to analyse more closely the issue of sharing the tax base. The subgroup was chaired by the Commission and met twice in Brussels in February and June 2007. The results of those meetings are summarized in two Commission Working Documents that were presented at the meetings of the main Working Group held after the meetings of the subgroup and can be found at the following web-page:

http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/taxation/company_tax/common_tax_base/article_3831_en.htm and http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/taxation/company_tax/common_tax_base/article_4381_en.htm

121 See Working Paper 47 (The mechanism for sharing CCCTB), Working Paper 52, (An overview of the main issues that emerge during the discussion on the mechanism for sharing CCCTB), paragraph III of Working Paper 55, (Summary record of the meeting of the CCCTN Working group) and Working Paper 60 (CCCTB: possible elements of the sharing mechanism).

122 Thus, for example a meeting with academic experts was held in March 2004 on “the allocation mechanism” and written contributions on the factors for apportioning income were requested and received at other stages of the consultation process.

123 Weiner (2005).

124 Agúndez-García (2006).

125 European Commission (2011a), "Impact assessment, accompanying document to the proposal for a

council directive on a common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) COM(2011) 121 final i", Commission Staff Working Document, SEC(2011) 316 final.

tax administrations to apply and easy for tax administrations to audit; (ii) be difficult for taxpayers to manipulate, that is, it should not rely on factors that can be easily relocated to exploit tax rate differentials across the EU; (iii) distribute the tax base among the various entities concerned in a way that can be considered fair and equitable; and (iv) not lead to undesirable effects in terms of tax competition. It was generally accepted that there should be a uniform formula across the EU, with the same factors and weights for all Member States.

The Commission's CCCTB apportionment mechanism constitutes a comparable system to what has been used in Canada, US and Switzerland to distribute income across subnational boundaries in the last century. The above mentioned countries employ formulas which attribute the tax base to taxing jurisdictions based on geographically determined factors. As such, the evaluation of the US and Canadian experience provided insight on the use of formulary methods and guidance for the Commission, limited in part by the different political structures at hand, as it designed an apportionment system for the

EU. 126 The Commission's choice of a uniform formula 127 and equally weighted factors, 128 the exclusion of intangible assets, 129 and the provision of sector-specific formulae 130 all stem in part from the lessons learned in the application of formulary

methods in North America.

A subtle difference between the US apportionment formula and the 2011 CCCTB apportionment formula is that the first is designed to apportion the tax base directly to a

particular state, whereas the later attributes income to its 'group members' 131 (which

results in an indirect attribution of income to the various Member States). Allocating the tax base to a group member assures that there is an EU Member State in which the base

will be taxable. 132

  • 4. 
    T REATMENT OF FORMULA APPORTIONMENT IN THE 2011 I MPACT A SSESSMENT

Along with the Directive, in 2011 the Commission released an Impact Assessment. 133

The impact of the apportionment formula on the following aspects is presented: (i) impact on distribution of the corporate tax bases among the EU Member States (ii) impact on the costs for tax administrations and on the compliance costs for taxpayers; (iii) the main economy-wide impacts.

126 Weiner (2006).

127 In contrast to the US where each state is free to choose its own formula, Member states in the EU are not allowed to apply domestic variations to the formula by attributing different weights to the factors. Non uniform formulae have led to distorting tax competition on the factors and double taxation (or double non taxation) in the US experience.

128 The US and Canada have employed formulas based on equally weighted origin-based supply and destination-based demand factors.

129 In the US intangibles are excluded from the asset factor.

130 For certain economic sectors, the predefined formula does not adequately reflect the importance of the various factors generating income. It is not uncommon for states to have special apportionment rules for certain industries; however, the industries differ from those proposed in the CCCTB.

131 See CCCTB Arts 4(7), 55.

132 This addresses the theoretical possibility that the formula allocates tax base to a Member State where the group has no taxable presence.

133 European Commission (2011), "Impact assessment, accompanying document to the proposal for a

council directive on a common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) COM(2011) 121 final i", Commission Staff Working Document, SEC(2011) 316 final.

The 2011 Impact Assessment includes the results from (i) PwC Study: (ii) Amadeus and Orbis database; and (iii) CORTAX study, which examine formula apportionment within the context of a wider analysis aiming to quantify the impacts of alternative policy options.

PwC case study: a survey was launched in 2008 among multinational companies located in the EU. One task of the study was to quantify the impact of alternative tax scenarios on the size of multinationals' taxable profit. Multinational companies were surveyed with a questionnaire on the quantitative and qualitative views on compliance under the current national systems for corporate income tax

and in the two hypothetical scenarios of CCTB and CCCTB. 134 Of the 21

multinational companies surveyed, 13 participated in the PwC taxable profits case study. The findings show that changing the weighing of the CCCTB apportionment factors has little effect on the relative apportionment of the tax base between countries. This result is attributed to a similar distribution of

apportionment factors across countries. 135

ORBIS and Amadeus databases: the databases provide balance sheets and profits and loss accounts for representative samples of about 6700 EU multinational groups in the financial and about 2000 groups in the non-financial sectors, respectively, over the 2002-2005 period. The data have been used to calculate the effect of loss consolidation and, with particular reference to ORBIS,

to calibrate the CORTAX model. 136 Using data from ORBIS and Amadeus

databases, shifts in the national tax bases after apportionment are evaluated by comparing the formulary apportionment-based distribution of tax bases across countries to the current profits-based distribution. Table 3 of the 2011 Impact Assessment reports the results from the formula where the labour factor (split into payroll and number of employees), assets and sales by destination are equally weighted. The consolidated EU tax base distributed using the formula would be larger in 12 Member States, smaller in 9 Member States, and unchanged in 2

Member States. 137 The effects of alternative formulae are also evaluated. 138

According to the study, the simulation of alternative sharing mechanisms, i.e. changing apportionment factors, has very small effects on aggregate EU welfare.

CORTAX model: an applied computable general equilibrium (CGE) model that describes the 27 countries of the EU at the time, plus the US and Japan. It is designed to simulate the economic implications of unilateral and multilateral corporate tax policies as well as the harmonisation of these policies. The model is calibrated using data from the ORBIS database. Importantly, the simulations in CORTAX are run under the working assumption that any changes in the corporate tax base would be compensated by changes in the national tax rates to

guarantee ex-ante budget neutrality. 139 Results include a quantification of welfare

effect of the reforms after firms' behavioural responses to the new tax system. In CORTAX, the shift from separate accounting to consolidation with formula apportionment has a number of effects: i) an impact on the distribution of

134 See annex 7 of the 2011 Impact Assessment for more details on this exercise.

135 See Table A.14 in annex 7 of the 2011 Impact Assessment.

136 See annex 3 of the 2011 Impact Assessment for a detailed description of the different ways in which the data have been used.

137 The result is undetermined for 4 Member States.

138 See Table A.11 in annex 3 of the 2011 Impact Assessment.

139 See annex 10 of the 2011 Impact Assessment for more detail.

corporate tax bases across countries; ii) a removal of profit shifting within the EU; iii) a shift from current distortions in international capital allocation towards a new type of distortion associated with the formula factors; iv) a reduction in tax compliance costs; v) the possibility to offset a loss in one Member State against profits in other Member States. In turn, the welfare effects under the CCCTB

have been simulated using alternative sharing mechanisms. 140 The switch to

payroll instead of employment mainly benefits high wage countries (in the former EU15) at the expense of low-wage countries (like Romania and Bulgaria). The larger weight on capital benefits capital-intensive countries like Belgium, Ireland and the Netherlands. On balance, CORTAX suggests that the isolated aggregate effect on welfare in the EU of any apportionment mechanism is very small. The discussion above assumes away other dynamic effects that would affect the size and distribution of the cake of corporate taxable profits in the EU in the longterm. CORTAX simulations show that with respect to economy-wide impacts, consolidation and apportionment have a positive economic effect. Overall the CCCTB implies a welfare gain of about 0.02% to 0.06% of GDP in aggregated terms for the EU as a whole.

  • 5. 
    F ORMULA A PPORTIONMENT IN THE E CONOMIC L ITERATURE

Formula apportionment has been the subject of analysis in a large body of literature, especially following the European Commission's interest in apportionment mechanisms. The choice and relative weighing of the factors to be used in the apportionment formula have been evaluated from an historical perspective, as well as from a conceptual and political basis. This section summarizes the most relevant contributions with a focus on findings in the literature after the 2011 proposal. The results of recent literature contribute to an understanding of the macroeconomic effects induced by the potential introduction of the CCCTB system.

In one of the first analyses of sharing mechanisms, Musgrave (1973) identifies the role of consolidation and formula apportionment in solving transfer pricing problems within multinational corporations. He points out that a formula for apportionment should be easy to administer and reflect the elements measuring the processes involved in the earning of net income. McLure (1980) shows theoretically that a corporate income tax which is applied through an apportionment formula is essentially equivalent to a direct tax levied on the factors of the formula. It follows that tax rate differences may distort the

allocation of formula apportionment factors. 141

As to the factors in the formula, literature discusses micro- and macroeconomic factors as possible choices. Schäfer and Spengel (2003) show that microeconomic (industry specific factors) are preferable to macroeconomic factors (which are market specific or linked to policy objectives) according to the principle of equity. Microeconomic factors better reflect each group member’s share in the income generating activities of taxable entities. Factors have also been individually analysed. For example, one essential matter of concern regarding the payroll factor for apportioning consolidated income, is the variance in wage levels across the EU, and hence the difference in labour costs across

Member States. 142 The number of employees is proposed as an alternative to the payroll

140 See Figure A.3 in annex 10 of the 2011 Impact Assessment.

141 See Gordon and Wilson (1986).

142 See also McLure (2002).

factor, with the premise that it may in turn lead to potential distortions due to differences

in the levels of labour productivity across the Member States. 143

Real and artificial factor shifting

The literature documents a range of potential tax avoidance strategies under formula apportionment. A study by Büttner et al. (2011) finds that profit-shifting activities of multinational entities remain important within formulary apportionment if companies are allowed to decide whether their affiliates are included in the consolidated group. Multinational entities can strategically exploit the definition of a consolidated group, by choosing to not consolidate if intra-group tax-rate differences are large, thereby preserving profit shifting opportunities. Their theoretical model of multinational entities shows that there are trade-offs to consolidation decision: "exclusion of affiliates costs (loss-offset opportunities foregone), but there is also a benefit of non-consolidation (maintaining profit-shifting opportunities)”. Greater dispersion of statutory tax rates increases the benefit of leaving affiliates in low-tax jurisdictions unconsolidated. This result is important for the EU and explains the choice of an 'all-or-nothing' option for including companies in the consolidated group and the mandatory requirement to remain within the CCCTB for five years. Furthermore, a study based on an experimental design finds indications that multinational entities opting for taxation on a consolidated basis may look for opportunities to shift profits to alternative investment locations outside the

European Union. 144

Generally though, formula apportionment systems are less subject to the manipulation of the tax base by companies through transfer pricing as discussed by Hellerstein (2005). Allocation rules, in comparison to separate accounting rules, reduce the ability of companies to use profit-shifting techniques, especially with regards to intra-group

financing. 145 Hence, formula apportionment is regarded as less vulnerable to tax avoidance practice 146 when compared to separate accounting tax regimes, where the

allocation of income among jurisdiction is strongly affected by profit shifting strategies

of multinational entities. 147 Studies also find that under formula apportionment systems there is less incentive for corporate tax rate competition. 148

On the other hand, there is evidence of tax-motivated factor shifting that entails real shifts in economic activity. For instance, empirically analysed impacts of a payroll formula apportionment regime on German business activity show a significant negative

correlation of the tax differential to payroll expense. 149 Firms react to incentives in a

formula apportionment tax regime by changing the allocation of real production factors,

i.e., shifting payroll to low-tax jurisdictions. 150 Distortions with respect to location

investment decisions have important policy implications. The impact varies among sectors: multinational entities in the manufacturing industry may have more potential to adjust the company structure to altered investment incentives under formula apportionment, in comparison to companies in other industries, such as the

143 For a discussion see Agundez-Garcia (2006).

144 See Keser et al. (2014).

145 See also Mintz and Smart (2004).

146 Clausing et al. (2011) discuss this point in more detail.

147 See Dharmapala (2014).

148 See Kind et al. (2005).

149 See among others Thomsen et al. (2014).

150 See also Eichfelder et al. (2015).

pharmaceutical industries. Finally, taking optimal pre-tax investment decisions as a given, a study of after-tax investment decisions of centrally managed multinational entities under a formula apportionment system, finds that incentives to invest in a taxoptimal

manner tend to be lower under formula apportionment. 151 The incentive to locate

apportionment factors in low-tax jurisdiction leads to economic distortions which are undesirable from an economic standpoint, highlighting the importance of the choice of

factors; however it does not raise abundant issues related to artificial tax shifting 152 .

  • 6. 
    C ONCLUSION

In sum, the formula apportionment rules proposed in 2011, which draw in part from the experiences with the formulary method in the US and Canada, were chosen for the following reasons: (i) the micro-factors composing the formula reflect the supply and demand sides of profit generating activities, (ii) the labour factor is split in two parts – payroll and employees –taking into account disparities in labour productivity across the EU, (iii) little sensitivity of the formula to different weights, i.e., changing the weights has little effect on the relative apportionment of the tax base, (iv) intangible and financial assets are excluded to prevent manipulation, (v) a uniform formula with identical factors and weights in all Member States taking part in the CCCTB avoids distorting tax competition and double taxation (or double non taxation), and finally (vi) the 'all-ornothing' approach limits tax-motivated manipulations of group structures.

Recent literature, including the contributions following the 2011 Directive, show that the determinants for the choice of factors as concluded in the 2011 CCCTB impact assessment remain relevant. There are certain risks for tax planning through 'factor shifting' under formula apportionment, but that these are very limited and would require a re-allocation of real factors, which is in general not mainly driven by tax considerations, but where other economic considerations play a more important role. In conclusion, the chosen sharing mechanism and the proposed formula reflect an approach which ensures that profits are taxed where economic activity as measured by the apportionment factors takes place.

151 See Ortmann and Erich (2015).

152 See Hellerstein (2012).

Annex VI: The Anti-Tax Avoidance Package

  • 1. 
    R ECENT D EVELOPMENTS

At the global level, the challenges related to the taxation of multinational companies have increased the political pressure to strengthen the international rules of co-operation in corporate tax matters. Following the crisis and the increased revenue needs, the OECD proposed an action plan on base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS) to reinforce the current international tax rules and stabilise national tax bases. The BEPS project focuses on the interaction of different (national) tax rules and tries to detect and close loopholes in the current tax architecture. The BEPS action plan laid the basis for developing an EU approach to implementing some international aspects of the common base that are linked to the OECD/G20 BEPS project. This allows for a coordinated implementation of the new international standards agreed in the package. The Treaties require that the fundamental rights – including the freedom of establishment – be respected. Reforms must therefore be tailored for the EU content and fix inconsistencies on an EU-wide basis.

The BEPS action plan was swiftly followed, in January 2016, by the Anti-Tax Avoidance Package. This package is made up of four proposals to ensure that tax is paid where the value is generated and that tax information is effectively accessed.

The Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive 153 puts forward tax rules aimed at preventing that

income goes untaxed (or taxed at very low level). It ensures coordination of the 28 national corporate rules in order to effectively limit aggressive tax planning. The Commission proposal covered the following rules: interest limitation rule, exit taxation, general anti-abuse rule, controlled foreign company rules, rules on hybrid mismatches and switch-over clause. The latter was not retained in the text agreed by the Council. The content of the agreed text is discussed in more detail below.

The Amendment to the existing Directive on administrative cooperation to implement Country-by-Country Reporting foresees the automatic exchange of information on country-by-country reports of multinational companies with consolidated revenues of at least EUR 750 million will have to provide tax-related information on an annual basis for each tax jurisdiction in which they do business. Member States will have to share the

information with the other Member States concerned. 154 The new rules, adopted by the

ECOFIN Council in May 2016, aim at enhancing transparency, thereby providing Member States with the information that they need to detect and prevent tax avoidance schemes.

The Recommendation on Tax Treaty issues advises Member States how to reinforce their tax treaties against abuse by aggressive tax planners in a way that is compliant with EU law. It covers the introduction of general anti-abuse rules in tax treaties and the revision of the definition of permanent establishment.

153 COM/2016/026 final

154 This information will be provided to the tax authorities of the Member States where the parent

company is established. If the parent company is not an EU tax resident, the reporting will be done through its EU subsidiaries.

The Communication on External Strategy for Effective Taxation sets out a coordinated EU approach against external risks of tax avoidance and to promote international tax good governance.

The Anti-Tax Avoidance Package complements existing initiatives and forums to ensure an effective taxation, enhance tax transparency and address the risk of double taxation. In particular, it focusses on:

• Transparency measures: In March 2015, the Commission launched a package of measures to boost tax transparency. It included a proposal for an automatic exchange of information on tax rulings, which was adopted by the Council in December 2015. All advance cross-border tax rulings and advance pricing arrangements will be subject to an automatic exchange of information as from January 2017. Further to the introduction of non-public Country-by-Country reporting, the Commission adopted in April 2016 a proposal to introduce public reporting requirements for multinational entities.

• Dispute resolution mechanism: The June action plan called for further improving the dispute resolution mechanism. The Commission is currently exploring various options for a coordinated EU approach to improve the current situation, following a public consultation.

• Joint Transfer Pricing Forum: The EU Joint Transfer Pricing Forum assists and advises the Commission on transfer pricing tax issues. It proposes non-legislative solutions to practical problems posed by transfer pricing practices in the EU. The work of the forum centres around two areas: the Arbitration Convention, which is a specific dispute resolution mechanism for transfer pricing cases; and the practical application of transfer pricing rules in the EU. The June action plan called on improving the transfer pricing framework in the EU in order to better align the transfer pricing outcomes with value creation.

  • 2. 
    T HE A DOPTED A NTI -T AX A VOIDANCE D IRECTIVE

The Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive puts forward tax rules aimed at preventing that income goes untaxed (or taxed at very low level). It ensures optimal coordination of the 28 national corporate rules in order to effectively limit aggressive tax planning. The proposal covers the following rules:

  • 1. 
    Interest Limitation Rule

Multinational enterprises have increasingly engaged in "shifting profits, often through inflated interest payments, out of high tax jurisdictions into countries with lower tax regimes. The interest limitation rule is necessary to discourage such practices by limiting the deductibility of taxpayers’ net financial costs" (source: proposal for a Directive COM 2016/026 final). The proposed Directive foresees that net interest expenses cannot be deducted above a fixed ratio (30%) expressed in terms of a taxpayer’s earnings before interest tax depreciation and amortisation (EBITDA). This is complemented by a group ratio rule, whereby the indebtedness of the overall group is considered for the purpose of entitling taxpayers to deduct higher amounts of net financial costs. Finally, a safeharbour provision foresees that companies that have net interest expenses below EUR 3 million are not caught by the rules as these companies are less likely to engage in debt shifting.

  • 2. 
    Exit taxation

Exit taxes aim at ensuring that states are in a position to tax the economic value of any capital gain created in their territory even though this gain has not yet been realised at the time of the exit. The proposed rule on exit taxation would allow taxpayers either to immediately pay the amount of exit tax assessed or defer payment of the amount of tax.

  • 3. 
    General anti-abuse rule (GAAR)

The GAAR complements specific anti-abuse rules. It ensures that tax avoidance strategies that were not envisaged by the legislator can be addressed, by granting the authorities the power to deny taxpayers the benefit of aggressive tax planning arrangements. The GAAR will apply domestically, intra-EU and internationally to taxpayer’s arrangements that are non-genuine.

  • 4. 
    Controlled foreign company rules (CFC)

CFC rules allow the reattribution of this income of a (low-taxed) controlled subsidiary to its parent company for tax purposes in certain situations. CFC rules therefore can ensure that profits parked in low or no tax countries are effectively taxed. The proposed rules cover both intra-EU and extra-EU situations.

  • 5. 
    Rules on hybrid mismatches

Hybrid mismatches arise from differences in the legal characterisation of payments (financial instruments) or entities in different jurisdictions. The directive includes rules to address hybrid mismatches in intra-EU situations, which should close the doors to exploiting such mismatches both for entities and transactions.

Annex VII: Compliance Costs

The reduction of tax compliance costs remains an important argument in the debate about harmonising the corporate tax base in the EU. The 2011 Impact Assessment analysed the consequences of a CCCTB on compliance costs based on survey results, notably for cross-border activities. This annex describes briefly the main finding on tax compliance costs. The first section explains the relevance of compliance costs and summarizes the main results from the literature. The second section reports the results of the 2011 Impact Assessment and discusses them in the light of the recent literature. The last section reviews the very limited information on the impacts on the costs of tax administrations.

  • 1. 
    T HE ROLE OF COMPLIANCE COSTS IN TAXATION

Taxation has a significant impact on business decisions. Taxes on businesses are indeed a key policy instrument of economic policy. One reason is that taxes can be changed relatively quickly in comparison to other important determinants of investment levels such as the public infrastructure or the skill level of the work force. Accordingly, tax policy is an attractive tool for policy makers to react quickly to different economic developments without too large time lags.

Taxation impacts businesses (and households) via three channels: (1) The tax payment which corresponds to the amount to be paid after the tax has been declared. (2) The welfare loss (deadweight loss) which arises from the economic distortions in (relative) prices due to taxation (tax wedge) and (3) the compliance costs incurred by businesses as well tax administrations for being tax compliant (or not), auditing and book keeping. While the first two channels feature prominently in the public economics literature, compliance costs are less discussed. One reason for this is the difficulty in measuring compliance costs properly.

Most research focuses on measuring compliance costs using survey techniques. The first step in order to isolate compliance costs for measurement is to define them properly. Tax compliance costs are commonly defined as the cost borne by businesses for complying with tax regulation, excluding the tax payment itself (Ramboll Management Consulting, 2013). The literature defines them as costs “incurred by taxpayers, or third parties such as businesses, in meeting the requirements laid upon them in complying with a given structure and level of tax” (Sandford, Godwin, and Hardwick 1989, p. 10).

From an economic perspective, compliance costs can be regarded as an efficiency loss and a waste of economic resources; they reduce private profits, but do not lead to higher tax revenue. Reducing compliance costs is therefore clearly beneficial and has been identified as a key objective in many national tax systems. In fact, most of the economic literature focuses largely on measuring and reducing domestic tax compliance costs. Evidence on cross-border tax compliance costs remains very scarce, although early contributions such as the 1992 Ruding report provided a first survey of cross-border compliance costs for EU companies. 965 companies of different size and sectors were part of the survey and estimated compliance costs were found to be at around 3% of their

total income. 155 The 2011 Impact Assessment has built on this work and provided some

more evidence on the size of the problem in the context of international investments.

Regarding the academic literature on the topic, Eichfelder and Vaillancourt (2014) provided an extensive survey of the current empirical estimates of tax compliance for different tax payers for the period between 1984 and 2014. For business taxes, the surveyed studies show that (domestic) compliance costs are regressive. For large companies they can be below 0.01% of turnover, while for SME the burden can be several percentage points and according to some studies even exceed the actual tax payment.

The literature as surveyed by Eichfelder and Vaillancourt (2014), as well as by Evans et al. (2014) shows regressive compliance costs and a decline in relative terms with the size of the business, whether measured by reference to turnover, income, number of employees or any other proxy. The evidence suggests that the share of tax planning costs in total compliance costs increases with company size. The research also shows that those compliance costs do not appear to be diminishing over time (Lignier and Evans 2012; Lignier, Evans and Tran-Nam 2014).

In conclusion, compliance costs remain a major investment impediment for companies both at the national level when complying with national rules, and at the international level when deciding on cross-border investments. In the latter case, compliance becomes even more costly since the rules of two countries have two be applied in addition to international tax rules which have to be considered (double tax treaties).

The CCCTB could make two contributions. Firstly, it can reduce compliance costs domestically since the system is easier and shorter than most national corporate income tax laws. Secondly and discussed in more detail below, it offers substantial improvements for companies which operate cross-border.

  • 2. 
    C OMPANIES TAX COMPLIANCE COSTS

Changeover costs

Estimating tax related compliance costs presents a number of well-known methodological difficulties. These are exacerbated when it comes to estimating costs stemming from the adoption of a new system. That these costs can be substantial in some cases is discussed by Eichfelder and Vaillancourt (2014) in the case of introduction of an indirect tax in Australia. However, there is no evidence from the literature for setting up a new CIT system. It should be emphasized that if the adoption of the new system were made optional for firms, the decision process would most likely be based on a costbenefit analysis that will itself take time and resources. For companies for which the CCCTB was mandatory, these specific costs were zero since a cost-benefit analysis was obsolete. For companies which are in the mandatory scope of the CCCTB or which optinto the system, learning costs should be expected from the compliance to the new rules. Table 33 reports the areas in which the surveyed multinationals expect costs from a changeover to arise according to a PwC study conducted for the 2011 Impact

155 The summary of compliance cost issues in the annex 2 of the 2001 Communication on Tax obstacles

in the internal market provides a summary of the results of the Ruding survey as well as a discussion of the literature available at the time.

Assessment. It should be noted that such costs will by definition be one-off costs, and hence be outweighed by the savings in recurring outlays that companies face in dealing with tax administrations.

Table 33: One-off costs expected to arise on a changeover from the current system

Type of cost % of respondents

Training staff 100.0%

Calculations to decide on whether to opt into CCCTB/CCTB 92.9%

Calculations to set up asset pool for tax depreciation under CCCTB/CCTB 85.7%

Development of new processes and systems 85.7%

Consulting/advisory fees 85.7%

Software license fees 64.3%

Other HR costs/relocation of staff 28.6%

Outsourcing compliance cost obligations 28.6%

Source: PricewaterhouseCoopers Survey on multinational firms.

Recurring compliance costs

Different methodologies have been used to quantify recurring compliance costs of the CCCTB. In particular, different surveys have been carried out among firms as well as among tax experts. The results of the PwC survey of 17 multinationals shows that the respondents predict, on average, an increase of 4% in time spent overall for corporate tax compliance activities in the event of a common base (see table 34). Although somewhat puzzling, small increases are expected in the time spent on record keeping, on the preparation of tax computation and on dealing with tax authorities. One reason for this surprising result could be that respondents implicitly assumed that the new legislation might lead to more exchanges and clarifications with tax administrations. Also, in the case of a common base there remains the need to provide a tax declaration in each Member State where the firm is active. In any case, the qualitative results show strong belief that the introduction of a common base will have little or no impact. An overwhelming majority of companies see the common base as equally burdensome across all the categories covered.

Regarding the shift to a CCCTB system, participants to the survey predicted, on average, a reduction of 8% in the time spent overall on corporate income tax compliance activities. The main areas where time savings are expected refer to transfer pricing documentation and to the preparation of tax computations. On the qualitative side, the CCCTB option is deemed by the majority of the respondents less burdensome than the current situation, with respect to the following areas: keeping up to date with rules and regulations; single filing of the tax return and dealing with a single tax authority; applying for clearances and rulings. The tasks of keeping records and dealing with formulary apportionment are expected to be more burdensome. Altogether, the qualitative picture confirms, on average, the quantitative estimation of an overall decrease of time devoted to tax compliance activities in the event of a CCCTB.

Table 34: Average changes in compliance time when moving from the current situation to CCTB and CCCTB

CCTB CCCTB

Record keeping 2% 1%

Transfer Pricing Documentation -1% -4%

Preparation of tax computations 1% -5%

Tax returns & payments 0% -1%

Dealing with the tax authorities 1% 2%

Mutual agreement procedures -1% -1%

Securing clearances and rulings 0% -1%

Learning and education 0% 0%

Total 4% -8%

Source: PricewaterhouseCoopers Survey on multinational firms.

Notes: Changes are expressed as a percentage change of the total time spent compared to the base case.

This data does not include the estimation of one-off variation due to the switching to another system. It relates to the permanent time spent associated with the new definition of the taxable base. The amount of compliance costs will depend on the wage level of employees in the different tax activities.

Switching the focus from existing companies to multinational enterprises that set up a new subsidiary in a different Member States, significantly higher compliance time and cost savings under the common base and most notably under the CCCTB regime can be expected. Through expert assessment, Deloitte estimated that under a situation with different tax codes in Member States, the additional recurrent compliance costs for a large representative parent investing in a medium sized subsidiary amounts to 0.23% of turnover, while for a medium parent this ratio more than doubles to 0.55% of turnover (see table 3). These figures amount to roughly EUR 141,000 and 128,000 respectively, calculated from the estimated compliance time.

Table 35: Compliance time and cost for setting up a new subsidiary

Large Parent

Current regime CCTB CCCTB

Time Cost Time % Diff. Cost % Diff. Time % Diff. Cost % Diff.

Record keeping for corporate tax purposes 5 261 3 740.60 3 063 -41.79% 2 992.46 -20.00% 3 592 -31.73% 5 708.94 52.62%

Transfer pricing documentation 22 255 36 165.74 22 162 -0.42% 36 143.08 -0.06% 0 -100.00% 0.00 -100.00%

Preparation of corporate tax computations 4 049 2 750.04 1 976 -51.19% 2 190.86 -20.33% 4 256 5.11% 4 761.47 73.14%

Prepayments for corporate tax 907 965.56 771 -14.99% 793.10 -17.86% 2 450 170.18% 2 662.13 175.71%

Corporate tax returns and payments 1 080 1 131.27 987 -8.58% 1 005.12 -11.15% 3 085 185.73% 3 505.17 209.84%

Dealing with the tax authorities for corporate tax 19 009 37 365.70 16 616 -12.59% 35,038.00 -6.23% 10 509 -44.71% 30 200.90 -19.17%

Mutual agreement procedures on transfer pricing 8 823 17 618.47 8 841 0.20% 17 677.73 0.34% 0 -100.00% 0.00 -100.00%

Clearances and rulings for corporate tax 14 430 34 912.77 14 541 0.77% 34,928.95 0.05% 1 288 -91.08% 3 996.90 -88.55%

Learning and education for corporate tax 10 000 5 220.08 8 264 -17.37% 5 388.20 3.22% 1 469 -85.31% 2 104.33 -59.69%

Any other cross-border corporate tax compliance formality 1 548 733.76 1 548 0.00% 733.02 -0.10% 0 -100.00% 0.00 -100.00%

Total estimated time spent/cost 87 362 140 603.97 78 768 -9.84% 136 890.52 -2.64% 26 649 -69.50% 52 939.85 -62.35%

Total estimated cost (% turnover) 0.23% 0.22% 0.09%

Table 35 (cont'd): Compliance time and cost for setting up a new subsidiary

Medium-sized Parent

Current regime CCTB CCCTB

Time Cost Time % Diff. Cost % Diff. Time % Diff. Cost % Diff.

Record keeping for corporate tax purposes 5 147 3 653.23 3 034 -41.05% 2 957.01 -19.06% 3 178 -38.26% 4 490.57 22.92%

Transfer pricing documentation 19 962 30 192.40 19 337 -3.13% 30 625.38 1.43% 0 -100.00% 0.00 -100.00%

Preparation of corporate tax computations 4 023 2 253.53 1 954 -51.42% 1 778.82 -21.07% 3 301 -17.94% 2 862.65 27.03%

Prepayments for corporate tax 896 636.81 760 -15.20% 524.54 -17.63% 1 880 109.73% 1 497.66 135.18%

Corporate tax returns and payments 1 075 871.48 987 -8.15% 790.31 -9.31% 2 433 126.34% 2 427.03 178.50%

Dealing with the tax authorities for corporate tax 18 686 32 968.18 16 347 -12.51% 30 604.60 -7.17% 10 675 -42.87% 24 889.54 -24.50%

Mutual agreement procedures on transfer pricing 8 609 17 076.44 8 434 -2.03% 17 115.31 0.23% 0 -100.00% 0.00 -100.00%

Clearances and rulings for corporate tax 13 893 34 175.02 14 083 1.37% 34 188.34 0.04% 1 266 -90.89% 3 958.48 -88.42%

Learning and education for corporate tax 9 997 5 201.14 8 422 -15.75% 5 579.09 7.27% 1 450 -85.49% 2 064.35 -60.31%

Any other cross-border corporate tax compliance formality 1 459 677.86 1 395 -4.42% 674.05 -0.56% 0 -100.00% 0.00 -100.00%

Total estimated time spent/cost 83 747 127 706.09 74 754 -10.74% 124 837.45 -2.25% 24 184 -71.12% 42 190.28 -66.96%

Total estimated cost (% turnover) 0.55% 0.54% 0.18%

Source: Deloitte Tax Experts survey.

Note: Time in minutes. Costs in Euros. Average of all investment flows

According to the study, the introduction of the CCTB would on average save

approximately 10% in compliance time and about 2.5% in compliance costs. 156 This

difference can be explained by the fact that higher savings in time are related to internal compliance activities (e.g. record keeping, preparation of tax computations, prepayments and tax returns and payments) estimated as less expensive compared to external advisors. Such savings are expected to occur because the CC(C)TB tax provisions are simpler and more stable compared to the current frequently changing tax environment. However, the main corporate compliance cost drivers are directly or indirectly related to transfer pricing (transfer pricing documentation, clearances and rulings and mutual agreement procedures), which account for about 60% of all compliance costs, remain unchanged (see figure 1). Due to the elimination or reduction of transfer pricing related compliance tasks, and of those related to contacts with tax authorities, an average decrease in total compliance time of 70% can be expected if the additional cross-border investment is

made under the CCCTB regime. 157 This results in a reduction of compliance costs of

62% for a group with a large parent and of 67% for a group with a medium-sized

parent. 158 The corresponding monetary figures are about 53,000 and 42,000 Euros

respectively. The high savings linked to the abolition of transfer pricing and the sharp reduction of costs in dealing with tax authorities are partly counterbalanced by other activities: corporate tax computations, (pre)payments and tax returns will be most likely

centralized at the level of the principal tax payer, normally the parent company. 159

However, all these tasks account only for about 10% of all compliance costs. All in all, as the figures in table 35 suggest, the size of the parent seems to have only a minor impact on total additional compliance time and costs savings under the CCTB and the CCCTB

regime. 160

156 The individual investment flow results by country-pairs range between 4% to 16% savings in additional compliance time and between -3% and 9% in compliance costs.

157 The individual results by country-pairs range between 11% to 91% savings in additional compliance

time. 158 Deloitte's tax experts expect that the group led by a medium parent can realise more savings on time

spent by external advisors that generally have higher costs per hour than the internal workforce.

159 The compliance time and cost savings would be even higher if it would be assumed that compliance

activities would be centralized at the level of the subsidiary ("CCCTB Sub lead"-scenario) operating in a low wage country, rather than at the level of the EU parent ("CCCTB Parent lead"-scenario).

160 The results are fairly robust with respect to the sensitivity analysis performed. First, it is assumed that

the parent company and the subsidiary belong to different sectors. This would depict a situation in which the central taxpayer lacks sector-specific and tax-related knowledge for its subsidiary. The assumption has no impact on compliance time under the current regime and the common base, whereas under the CCCTB regime an increase of 8% of compliance time can be expected. Accordingly, the savings of compliance time and cost compared to the current situation would slightly diminish to 65% and 50 % respectively. Second, if the investing company would be only a single company without intra-group transactions significant lower compliance time can be expected for the current regime and the common base whereas for the CCCTB, without the transfer pricing related task, compliance time remains the same compared to the baseline investment. Again, in this case the savings due to the CCCTB compared to the current regime would be smaller than in the baseline scenario.

Figure 23: Compliance time spent on setting up a new subsidiary

Compliance time spent on setting up a new subsidiary

  • - 
    Large parent, average of all countries investigated -

    Thousands of minutes

100 TP MUTUAL AGRREEMENT PROCEDURES

90 TP DOCUMENTATION

80 CLEARANCES AND RULINGS

70 LEARNING AND EDUCATION

60 DEALING WITH TAX AUTHORITIES

50 RECORD KEEPING

40 PREPARATION OF COMPUTATIONS

30 PREPAYMENTS

20 TAX RETURNS AND PAYMENTS

10 ANY OTHER

0

Current CCTB CCCTB

Source: Deloitte Tax Experts Survey

  • 3. 
    T AX ADMINISTRATIONS

Measuring the cost of tax administrations for levying a specific tax is a very difficult task and has become even more difficult in recent years. The reason is that most tax administrations (and the corresponding IT systems) are organised by functions and not any more by type of tax. While there have been some attempts to calculate the front office costs for single tax, these efforts led to limited information since back office functions and costs (namely audit and debt collection) are estimated globally, and then apportioned according to the share of each tax in the total revenue, or to the audit or enforcement yield. In the context of the discussion here, this means that there is no readily available data on the direct impact on tax administrations. In the following, we elaborate on some qualitative arguments related to an introduction of a CCCTB and its impact on tax administrations.

A move to any of the alternative policy options from the current situation will entail some new costs for Member States' tax administrations. These costs include: the need for coordination with other administrations (for example, in the application of double taxation relief methods) and one-off costs like the need of personal training, upgrading of IT systems, etc. Some of the alternative systems may save some of the current costs which tax administrations incur, such as the costs of resolving intra-EU transfer-pricing disputes or the general costs of monitoring transfer-price setting by companies (these costs would be saved only by a CCCTB, but would remain in place under the common base, since it would still operate under separate accounting). In case of optional policy alternatives, the costs associated with maintaining two different systems simultaneously should be estimated. These costs would be saved in the compulsory versions of the CCCTB, where this alternative tax scheme would replace all current national corporate tax systems.

The parallel application of national CIT systems and the CCCTB will increase administrative burden in tax administrations since two, albeit similar taxes need to be managed. However, since multinational companies under the scope of the CCCTB will only file one tax declaration in the EU, the total amount of tax declarations should decline and ease the burden for tax administrations. Also, the fact that no more transfer pricing documentation is necessary in the EU will reduce the burden on administrations. The compliance costs for companies will decline for those cases where cross-border investments are involved – partly because of the abolition of transfer pricing documentation, more generally because there is only one set of rules to comply with. Given the fact that the CCCTB is more streamlined than national systems, one could expect that also domestic compliance costs are reduced. In any case, the choice to enter the CCCTB will reflect compliance cost considerations, both for domestic firms and for MNEs not subject to mandatory application. Generally, data on these questions are scarce or in some cases missing.

Annex VIII: The 2011 Proposal for a CCCTB

  • 1. 
    T AX OBSTACLES IN THE SINGLE MARKET AND THE 2011 PROPOSAL FOR A CCCTB

While the integration of markets has made substantial progress in recent decades, the same cannot be said for the taxation of income from pan-EU activities, which remains largely a national task. This can lead to frictions in the single market due to tax obstacles and has been recognized as a concern early in the European integration process.

The primary focus was on preventing problems which could hamper the development of the single market, such as double taxation and tax discrimination. The Commission has highlighted the issues and challenges of corporate tax systems in an Economic Union as well as their role for competitiveness vis-à-vis third countries for many decades. Proposals for reforming corporate taxation have been discussed in the European Union since at least 1962 when the Neumark Committee called to gradually harmonize tax systems in Europe. It was followed by the 1970 van den Tempel report and the 1992 Ruding report. In 1998 the Code of Conduct for business taxation was established to limit harmful tax competition and identify specific tax regimes considered harmful. In the same year, rules on the application of the State Aid rules to measures relating to direct business taxation were published by the Commission. In 2001, the Commission presented a Communication identifying concrete steps to eliminate tax obstacles to crossborder trade in the EU. This was followed by ten years of technical preparation,

culminating in the Commission's 2011 proposal for a CCCTB. 161

On 16 March 2011, the Commission tabled a proposal for a directive on a CCCTB which lays down common rules for the calculation of the tax base applicable to companies operating in the EU. This EU tax framework comprises a full set of corporate tax rules to calculate the individual fiscal results of companies and permanent establishments which are tax resident, or situated, in the EU. The system includes rules for consolidating those results (profits and losses) when there are other group members and to apportion the consolidated tax base to all relevant Member States if it is positive. In other words, a qualifying company or group of companies would have to comply with only one set of rules for computing its taxable income, rather than different rules in each Member State where it operates. The consolidated tax base would be apportioned on the basis of a fixed formula comprising three equally weighted factors: sales (by destination), labour and assets. Each Member State would apply its own tax rate to the share of the tax base apportioned through the formula. Only the calculation and apportionment of the tax base would be harmonised. Member States would retain the power to set their own tax rates.

In 2011, the CCCTB was proposed as an optional system. All companies, irrespective of size or whether they had cross-border operations, would be entitled, but not obliged, to apply the system, provided that they fulfilled the eligibility requirements of the Directive. A company which opted for the CCCTB would be committed to apply the system for an initial term of five years. This would automatically be extended for successive periods of three years unless a company applying the system as a single taxpayer or a group, as the

161 In addition, several academic reports called for more harmonisation in the field of corporate taxation.

See e.g. Klemm and Radaelli (2001) or Spengel and Zöllkau (2012) for two prominent contributions to the debate.

case may be, filed a notice of termination in the three months before a period of applicability expired.

The proposal also includes anti-abuse rules and stipulates how Member States should administer the CCCTB under a 'one-stop-shop' approach.

In 2011, the CCCTB was primarily envisaged as a tool for removing tax obstacles which companies occasionally suffer when they operate cross-border within the Internal Market. Companies would thus benefit from cross-border loss relief, which is an automatic outcome of consolidation (i.e. no more paying tax on profits in one Member State to the extent that unrelieved losses are being made at the same time in another Member State). The apportionment of the tax base through a formula would remove the requirement for lengthy and costly recording and negotiating of intra-group transactions at notional arm's length prices (i.e. no more transfer pricing within a CCCTB group). Accordingly, compliance costs would be reduced by providing for a single set of tax rules for calculating the tax base, instead of the 27 at the time. Having a common set of rules would also reduce the possibility of double taxation or double non taxation and mismatches in general.

  • 2. 
    WORK ON THE CCCTB PROPOSAL DURING 2011-2016

Intensive technical discussions and an article-by-article detailed analysis amongst national experts in Council followed tabling the proposal for a CCCTB. After a first reading was completed, the High Level Working Party (HLWP) agreed in March 2013 that work on the proposal should be structured as a step-by-step approach and Member States should prioritise the matters related to the tax base. Accordingly, consolidation would have to be addressed in a second step once the work on the base would have been sufficiently advanced. At the time, Member States also stated that the proposal was not yet ready for a political discussion. The Presidency was invited to draft a compromise text on that basis.

After technical work on the elements of the tax base (i.e. skeleton - main computations, timing and quantification, depreciation, treatment of losses) was accomplished under the subsequent Presidencies (i.e. Lithuania & Greece), the Italian Presidency shifted its attention towards highlighting the link between the CCCTB and the OECD initiative against Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS). In this framework, discussions focussed on the international aspects of the tax base as well as certain elements of the CCCTB system, such as controlled foreign company (CFC) legislation and the interest limitation rule (first inserted in a compromise text by the Presidency of Denmark). Both are closely linked to the OECD BEPS work.

At the informal ECOFIN of October 2014, the Council discussed how to make concrete progress on the CCCTB in the short to medium term. As outcome of this debate, the Presidency concluded that future work on the CCCTB proposal should primarily be centred on the international aspects of the system (in particular, Controlled Foreign Company legislation and anti-abuse measures, hybrid mismatches, the interest limitation rule and a definition of permanent establishment).

In the wake of the publication of the OECD BEPS action plan conclusions in October 2015, the Luxembourg Presidency resumed the in-depth technical examination of the international and anti-abuse aspects of the CCCTB, with the aim to facilitate a coordinated implementation of the OECD recommendations in the EU. In the meantime, the Commission's action plan on Corporate Taxation of June 2015 had already announced a comprehensive re-launch of the CCCTB proposal in 2016. In line with its EU BEPS roadmap, the Presidency launched a discussion on the opportunity of splitting the CCCTB proposal, in order to attempt a speedy adoption of the BEPS related and international aspects. In July 2015, most delegations supported such a split and suggested that the "anti-BEPS directive" address both third countries and intra-EU situations. At the following technical meetings in Council, the Presidency brought further clarifications as to how such EU legislation could materialise more concretely. In this context, the Presidency reflected BEPS related issues which had already been subject to technical examination into a consolidated text of the prospective “anti-BEPS” directive.

On 28 th January 2016 and while work on the re-launched CCCTB proposal was

progressing, the Commission tabled a proposal for a directive against tax avoidance practices. As a matter of fact, the proposed instrument included most of the elements of the international and BEPS related aspects of the CCCTB in an effort to lay down a coordinated approach to implementing certain common minimum standards against tax avoidance in the EU.

  • 3. 
    T HE IMPACT ASSESSMENT FOR THE 2011 PROPOSAL

The analysis underlying key features of the 2011 proposal was based on many years of work and input from within the Commission, external contractors and Member States (CCCTB Working Group) as well as other stakeholders (including academia, tax administrations, business and professional associations, think tanks). The CCCTB Working Group was created in 2004 and held its last meeting in October 2010. The group produced 68 papers and summary records of their meetings, all published on a

dedicated DG TAXUD website. 162

Compliance costs

The main findings from the analysis were that firms' tax compliance costs are high and significant, mostly due to frequent changes and complexity of tax laws, and that they are regressive: The estimate for large companies is about 2% of taxes paid, while for small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) the figure is about 30% of taxes paid. Compliance costs increase with cross-border activity and with increasing number of subsidiaries, have not reduced over time and in particular the transfer pricing compliance burden has increased over time.

For tax administrations, the 2011 Impact Assessment anticipated that they would benefit mainly from saving costs in relation to transfer pricing (monitoring, dispute resolution). At the same time there would be an additional cost for maintaining two systems in parallel (Annex 9 of the 2011 Impact Assessment). For companies, optionality would require a decision whether to opt into the system, but arriving at the optimal decision entails a cost-benefit analysis, which takes resources. Focussing on recurring costs, i.e. ignoring one-off switching costs, an increase in time spent on compliance activities by 4% was expected for the CCTB and a decrease by 8% for the CCCTB. Time costs for setting up a new subsidiary in a Member State were estimated to decrease by 10-11% for the CCTB and 62-67% for the CCCTB.

162 http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/taxation/company_tax/common_tax_base/index_en.htm

Other tax obstacles in the single market

These obstacles mainly referred to 'over-taxation' and double taxation. Over-taxation occurs whenever cross-border activities lead to tax liabilities that would not have occurred in a domestic context. Based on the public consultation conducted for the 2011 Impact Assessment, double taxation occurs mainly in the context of cross-border business restructurings or due to different tax treatments of transfer prices in different Member States. Another source for double taxation is heterogeneity in double taxation treaties and their interpretation. The increased number of requests received under the EU Arbitration Convention between 2004 and 2008, along with the unresolved pending cases, has also been seen as evidencing continued problems in the area of transfer pricing.

Since only a few Member States offer limited forms of cross-border loss compensation, groups operating cross-border have substantially fewer possibilities to offset losses compared to domestic groups in most Member States (some do not provide any kind of loss relief). Moreover, the limited or non-existing cross-border loss offset implies differences in tax treatment of foreign permanent establishments and foreign subsidiaries. The 2011 Impact Assessment notes "several further potentially important economic effects of (cross-border) loss compensation: (i) improved neutrality between domestic and cross-border investment; (ii) reduced risk of investment, as losses are better insured (Domar-Musgrave effect), which may stimulate risk-taking and raise returns to capital in the economy; (iii) increased efficiency in the international allocation of productive capital; (iv) enhanced investment ability from financially constrained firms following higher after-tax profits". Based on this, it was concluded that consolidation would be apt to reducing over-taxation of cross-border economic activities and thereby improve efficiency in the internal market. The quantitative analysis found that in a given year 50% of non-financial and 17% of financial multinational groups could benefit from immediate cross-border loss offset, leading to additional losses as a share of net current taxable profits of 3% for the average non-financial group and 2.5% for the average financial group. A PWC case study with 13 multinational companies found substantially higher figures. The Computable General Equilibrium model used to simulate the reform pointed to an a priori reduction of 15% in the corporate tax base and in the new equilibrium, where the reform is designed in a budget neutral way, of about 4.5%.

Formula apportionment

The 2011 Impact Assessment concluded to allocate the consolidated tax base to a 'group member A' according to the following formula:

Share A = � 1 𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆

𝐴𝐴 𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴 1 𝑁𝑁𝑃𝑃 𝑃𝑃𝑜𝑜 𝑆𝑆𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴 1 𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆 𝐴𝐴

3 𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 +

1 1

3 � 2 + 𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 + 2 𝑁𝑁𝑃𝑃 𝑃𝑃𝑜𝑜 𝑆𝑆𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑆𝑆𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 � + 3 𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝐴𝐴𝑆𝑆 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 � .

∗ 𝐶𝐶𝑃𝑃𝑛𝑛 ′ 𝑑𝑑 𝑇𝑇𝑆𝑆𝑇𝑇 𝐵𝐵𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆

Aside from the extensive work by the CCCTB Working Group and consultations with stakeholders, three specific pieces of analysis were included in the Impact Assessment in order to compare the impact of different formulas: (i) a PWC survey of multinational entities on compliance costs: (ii) impact of variations in the formula on the distribution of tax bases across countries, using the Amadeus and ORBIS databases; and (iii) the CORTAX study, which examined formula apportionment within the context of a wider analysis aiming to quantify the impacts of alternative policy options. The formula was evaluated against four criteria: 1. Simplicity for taxpayers and administrations; 2.

Difficult to manipulate, i.e. no easy relocation of factors to exploit tax-rate differentials across the EU; 3. Fair and equitable distribution of the tax base; 4. No negative impact on tax competition. More details on the rationale for the formula that was chosen can be found in Annex V: Formula apportionment.

Depreciation regime

Based on work by the CCCTB Working Group, it was decided that fixed assets would be depreciable for tax purposes with the exception of financial assets and those tangible assets not subject to wear and tear and obsolescence. Fixed assets are all tangibles, those intangibles acquired for a value where they are capable of being valued independently and are used in the business in the production, maintenance or securing of income for more than 12 months. The concept also includes financial assets (although these are excluded from depreciation) but not assets of a small value (i.e. where the cost of their acquisition, construction or improvement is less than EUR 1 000). Depreciable long-life (at least 15 years) tangible and intangible fixed assets would be depreciated individually. Remaining assets would go into a pool, which should simplify matters for both tax authorities and taxpayers since it avoids the need to establish and maintain a list of every single type of fixed asset and its useful life. Regarding the generosity level of the depreciation allowances, the CORTAX simulations showed that the results improved with increasing generosity of depreciation allowances. Accordingly, from the two options on the depreciation regime for the pooled assets that were examined, the more generous one was chosen.

Economic impacts

As for the present impact assessment, the economy-wide impacts were analysed based on

CORTAX simulations (Box 1 explains the features for the updated version of the model used in this impact assessment). The CCTB and CCCTB were assessed, with two variations on the scope (optional for all firms or compulsory for all firms) and three variations on the depreciation regime. Since the CORTAX model cannot reasonably capture the opt-in choice, it was assumed that all multinational entities would opt for the CCCTB. The conclusion drawn based on the simulations was that the CCCTB was preferable to the CCTB due to slightly better impacts on welfare. The conclusion on the scope hinged on the depreciation regime. Under a base broadening reform (i.e. stricter depreciation regime than in the baseline), it was better to make the CCCTB optional, whereas a compulsory application was better with a more generous depreciation regime.

Preferred option in the 2011 Impact Assessment

The CCCTB was chosen over the CCTB, based on the CORTAX results and the

CCCTB's clearly superior results in terms of compliance cost savings and reduction in other tax obstacles. Moreover, since only base broadening reforms were seriously considered based on input from the CCCTB WG, the preferred option was the one that would make the CCCTB optional for all firms. It should be kept in mind though that in terms of economic impacts this corresponded to the scenario in which all multinational entities applied the CCCTB.

Annex IX: Impact of the CCCTB on intra-group profit shifting

Table 36: Impact of the CCCTB on intra-group profit shifting

Member State Baseline CCCTB Change

Outward Inward Outward Inward Outward Inward

AT -0.3% 2.6% 0.0% 0.2% -100.0% -91.8%

BE -9.0% 2.9% 0.0% 1.5% -100.0% -50.1%

DK -0.3% 4.4% 0.0% 0.9% -100.0% -78.3%

FI 0.0% 2.9% 0.0% 0.4% -100.0% -86.9%

FR -7.7% 0.1% 0.0% 0.7% -100.0% 720.4%

DE -1.1% 0.7% 0.0% 0.2% -100.0% -74.1%

EL -0.2% 1.4% 0.0% 0.3% -100.0% -80.5%

HR -0.2% 11.6% 0.0% 0.2% -100.0% -98.0%

IE 0.0% 16.5% 0.0% 0.8% n/a -95.1%

IT -1.5% 0.9% 0.0% 0.3% -100.0% -70.2%

LU -1.8% 8.6% 0.0% 2.2% -100.0% -74.0%

NL -0.7% 11.1% 0.0% 1.9% -100.0% -82.9%

PT -1.0% 1.8% 0.0% 0.2% -100.0% -90.9%

ES -2.5% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% -100.0% -78.8%

SE -1.1% 3.2% 0.0% 1.6% -100.0% -49.1%

UK -0.1% 6.1% 0.0% 0.3% -100.0% -95.3%

CY 0.0% 10.0% 0.0% 2.1% n/a -78.7%

CZ 0.0% 3.5% 0.0% 0.2% -100.0% -94.4%

EE -1.1% 4.7% 0.0% 0.4% -100.0% -90.7%

HU 0.0% 4.1% 0.0% 0.8% -100.0% -81.2%

LV -0.1% 4.9% 0.0% 0.3% -100.0% -94.6%

LT 0.0% 3.6% 0.0% 0.1% -100.0% -97.9%

MT -5.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% -100.0% -98.3%

PL 0.0% 2.2% 0.0% 0.1% -100.0% -97.3%

SK -0.1% 4.5% 0.0% 0.1% -100.0% -96.8%

SL 0.0% 4.9% 0.0% 0.0% -100.0% -99.2%

BG 0.0% 4.6% 0.0% 0.2% n/a -96.2%

RO 0.0% 2.7% 0.0% 0.1% -100.0% -96.2%

Average* EU-28 -1.5% 5.5% 0.0% 1.0% -100% -82.2%

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

Notes: The values indicate changes in percent to the theoretical tax base without intra-group profit shifting. Take for example Italy and assume it had a corporate income tax base amounting to 100 in the theoretical case where profit shifting via transfer pricing would not be feasible for multinational entities. The baseline results indicate that allowing for profit shifting via transfer pricing would lead to the new tax base of 100- 1.5+0.9=99.4. In other words, in the baseline scenario, Italy loses 1.5% of its corporate tax base due to multinational entities shifting profits to other countries and gains 0.9% of its tax base due to multinational entities shifting profits to Italy. Under the CCCTB, profits would no longer be shifted to other countries as it would not reduce tax liabilities (i.e. outward equals zero). There remains a small inward shift of 0.3% which is profits shifted to Italy from the US and Japan. *Average refers to the weighted EU average of the individual country values.

Annex X: Measuring the cost of capital and effective average tax rates

This impact assessment uses analysis of the existing differences in effective corporate tax rates within the EU. The aim is to detect possible tax induced distortions to the allocation of resources in both domestic and international investments in a theoretical framework which allows country comparisons. The analysis of the impact of taxation on investment behaviour requires forward-looking indicators which include a large majority of the relevant tax provisions relevant for corporate investment.

The annual report on effective tax levels in the EU carried out by the ZEW applies a forward-looking approach originally developed by Devereux and Griffith (1998a, 1998b) and provides a comprehensive analysis of the effects of tax legislation on investments for all 28 EU Member States and selected third countries.

The basic approach is to consider a hypothetical incremental investment located in a specific country that is undertaken by a company resident in the same country or in another country. Two tax measures are computed: the cost of capital and the effective average tax rate. The cost of capital measures the required minimum pre-tax return of a real investment (the 'marginal investment') to achieve the same after-tax return as a safe investment in the capital market. The standard assumption by the ZEW for the real return on the safe investment is 5%. The lower the cost of capital the more investments are undertaken. If the cost of capital is exactly equal to the return from a safe investment, the tax system does not distort the scale of investments. This approach is based on the presumption that firms undertake all investment projects that earns at least the required rate of return.

A complementary approach is to consider discrete choices for profitable investments and in particular discrete location choices. The effective average tax rate measures the relative difference between a fixed rate of pre-tax return of a profitable investment (the

standard assumption by the model is 20%) and its after-tax return. 163 The effective

average tax rate is thus a measure of the attractiveness of a tax system.

In both cases, the hypothetical investment takes place in one period and generates a return in the next period. The impact of taxation is analysed by considering a number of features of the tax system, including the statutory tax rate, capital allowances, the treatment of interest deduction, the allowance for corporate equity, the treatment of foreign source income, wealth taxes paid by the company, as well as possibly the treatment at the corporate and personal level of dividends paid by the company, and

wealth and capital gains taxes at the personal level. 164

Both the cost of capital and the effective average tax rate are computed for five different types of assets (intangibles, buildings, machinery, financial assets, inventory) and three different sources of financing (retained earnings, new equity, debt). Further, both measures are computed for the corporate level and the shareholder level, considering three different types (zero-rate, top-rate non-qualified and top-rate qualified shareholder) and can thereby be used to compare the relative distortions introduced by the tax system in relation to certain investments or financing sources both at the corporate level and shareholder level.

163 The effective average tax rate equals the effective marginal tax rate if the profitability is equal to the

cost of capital. 164 It is assumed that the tax system remains unchanged over the life of the investment.

In presenting averages over different forms of assets, these assets are weighted equally, while unequal weights are used for financing: retained earnings 55%, new equity 10% and debt 35% (based on OECD, 1991). As for true economic depreciation rates it is assumed: intangibles (15.35%), industrial buildings (3.1%); machinery (17.5%), financial assets (0%), and inventories (0%).

In the context of this Impact Assessment, two studies using the methodology described above were produced by the ZEW. The first report analyses the impact of debt-bias reforms on the cost of capital and effective average tax rates as well as the consequences of a revenue neutral implementation. Four debt-bias reforms are considered: a no interest deductibility (Comprehensive Business Income Tax, CBIT), Allowance for Corporate Equity (ACE), Allowance for Corporate Capital (ACC), Cost of Capital Allowance (CoCA).

A second report analyses the impact of certain tax planning strategies on tax burden measures. The tax planning strategies considered involve profit shifting via cross-border structures generally available to multinational corporations. Profit shifting channels from high-tax to low-tax countries cover intra-group debt shifting, royalty payments and the use of hybrid instruments.

Annex XI: Existence and design of R&D tax incentives in the EU

Table 37: R&D Incentives by EU Member States

Type of R&D tax incentive Type of Tax

Expense-based Input-based

Country

Accelerated Existing Tax credits Enhanced expense

Corporate

allowance depreciation based Patent Box income

Personal Wage tax /

incentive tax

income tax SSCs

BE X X X X X X X

BG X X X X

CZ X* X X X

DK X X X X X

DE

EE

IE X X X X

EL X X X X

ES X X X X

FR X X X X X X

HR X X X

IT X X X X X

CY X X X X

LV X X X X

LT X X X X

LU X X X X

HU X X X X X

MT X X X X

NL X X X X X X X

AT X X X X X

PL X* X X X X X

PT X X X X

RO X X X X

SI X X X X X

SK X X X

FI

SE X X X

UK X X X X X X

EU 15 15 10 24 13 24 6 7

Norway X X X

Canada X X X X X X

US X X X X

Israel X* X X X X

Japan X X X X X

Source: CPB(2014)

Notes: The temporary scheme in Finland has expired. Ireland has introduced a knowledge box.

*: Reduced corporate tax rate. SSCs stands for social security contributions.

Table 38: Reduction in the effective tax burden from R&D tax incentives across firm size

Firm Size Effective tax burden reduction from R&D tax incentives Effective tax burden reduction from combination of SME incentives and R&D incentives

Large From less than -1% (Luxembourg) to -20% (Lithuania). Not applicable

[Reduction in 15 countries among 20 countries considered]

Tax base incentives Tax liability incentives From -0.2% (France) to -20% From -3% (The Netherlands) to - (Lithuania) 6% (Ireland)

[Reduction in 14 countries [Reduction in 7 countries among among 20 countries 20 countries considered considered]

Medium From less than -1% (Luxembourg) From less than -1% to -25% (Ireland). (Luxembourg)

[Reduction in 16 countries among 20 countries considered] to -25% (Ireland).

Small From less than -1% (Luxembourg) From less than -1% to -22% (Ireland). (Luxembourg)

[Reduction in 16 countries among 20 countries considered] to -33% (Ireland).

Source: VVA and ZEW (2015)

Annex XII: The impact on tax revenues

Baseline vs CCCTB using CORTAX

The CORTAX simulations allow for some stylised insights on the impact on tax revenues. Interpretation of these values should however be done with caution as a number of factors impact on revenues. First, the calibration of the model tries to replicate the baseline corporate tax bases for each Member State and, while this is done in the best possible way to capture the EU-28 values, there remain some differences between the actual and the simulated tax base for some Member States. Moreover and importantly, the model makes the hypothesis that governments change ex-ante (that is before the behavioural impact is taken into account) the corporate income tax rate for the CCCTB in order to compensate for differences in the rules to compute the corporate tax base. This is a technical – and necessary for model closure – assumption. In reality national governments would be free to adjust tax rates in other ways. Overall, Table 39 shows the

impact on tax revenues for individual Member States and for the EU-28 as a whole. 165

The results are difficult to interpret, for a number of reasons that are discussed below. More importantly, there is a downward bias as they capture only in a limited manner the positive impact on revenues due to the expected reduction in corporate tax avoidance. Notably, the model does not cover the positive impact from the effective elimination in the CCCTB of the use of patent boxes, the exploitation of hybrid mismatches and profit shifting via intra-group debt shifts. Under the assumptions of the model, corporate tax revenues are expected to decline by 0.27% of GDP. The largest decrease would amount to 1% of GDP for Luxembourg, whereas at the other extreme corporate income tax revenues would increase by 0.19% of GDP in Croatia. The impact on overall tax revenues in the EU-28 is considerably smaller as losses in corporate tax collection are partly compensated for by a higher collection of labour taxes driven by the positive impacts on employment and wages. They decrease by 0.08% of GDP, ranging from a decrease of -0.95% of GDP in Luxembourg to an increase of 0.29% of GDP in Croatia.

Individual results are subject to large caveats. Changes in corporate tax revenues are influenced in many different ways in the model and most impacts are not uniform across countries: (1) The CCCTB changes the depreciation rules. For some countries this means a decrease in the tax base, for others it implies an increase. (2) Corporate income tax rates are adjusted ex-ante to compensate for the changes in the base computation. (3) Profit shifting via transfer pricing within the EU is no longer beneficial. This impact goes in different directions for different Member States. The model tends to underestimate this effect. (4) Consolidation of profits and losses within a company group tends to reduce the overall tax base. (5) Formula apportionment distributes the tax base differently across Member States compared to the existing separate accounting system. In addition, both corporate income tax revenues and other tax revenues are impacted by the predicted macroeconomic changes, notably with respect to GDP and labour market outcomes.

165 The impact from introducing the Allowance for growth and investment and the R&D tax incentives are treated separately because the CORTAX model does not replicate the fact that an Allowance for Growth and Investment is less generous than a full-fledged ACE and it does not cover the R&D tax incentives.

Due to the assumed adjustment in corporate income tax (CIT) rates and the many different interactions of different impacts, the change in tax revenues is difficult to predict for each individual Member State.

Table 39: Impact on tax revenues by tax type (in % of GDP) of the CCCTB – only multinational entities

Corporate Labour Consump Tax on Tax on Tax on tax tax tion tax bonds dividends capital

Total tax

gains revenues

Austria -0.14 0.05 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.09

Belgium -0.08 0.09 0.06 -0.01 0.00 0.00 0.06

Denmark -0.12 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.08

Finland -0.07 0.08 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03

France -0.13 0.06 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.06

Germany -0.24 0.09 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.01 -0.12

Greece 0.03 -0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01

Croatia 0.19 0.06 0.05 -0.01 0.00 0.00 0.29

Ireland -0.14 0.10 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02

Italy -0.04 0.03 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Luxembourg -1.01 0.03 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.95

Netherlands -0.19 0.29 0.12 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.22

Portugal -0.03 0.07 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.07

Spain -0.61 0.31 0.03 0.04 0.01 0.02 -0.20

Sweden -0.12 0.15 0.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.09

UK -0.88 0.30 0.04 0.11 0.02 0.04 -0.37

Cyprus -0.02 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01

Czech Rep -0.05 0.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01

Estonia 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.07

Hungary -0.08 0.08 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.01

Latvia 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.05

Lithuania 0.08 -0.03 -0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04

Malta -0.55 0.20 0.04 0.06 0.01 0.04 -0.2

Poland -0.14 0.10 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.01 -0.01

Slovakia 0.02 0.06 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.09

Slovenia -0.01 0.08 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.09

Bulgaria 0.00 0.10 0.03 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.14

Romania -0.01 0.05 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.05

EU -0.27 0.13 0.02 0.02 0.00 0.01 -0.08

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

Debt bias

Next, we turn to the possible revenue impacts of the debt bias. Revenue impacts are difficult to assess for non-deductibility of interest and the ACC since none of the systems have so far been implemented. For the non-deductibility of interest, however, a back-ofthe-envelope calculation can provide a rough estimate based on aggregate company data. Table 40 shows that interest on financial debt represents a sizeable share of profit before

tax. Column (6) shows that values vary between about 15 and 40% of profit before tax. 166

Assuming that the non-deductible amount would be taxed at the same average rate as the other profits, the results suggest an increase in corporate income tax collected of between 0.4 and 1% of GDP. Obviously, this result needs to be taken with extreme caution as it is based on strong stylised assumptions and does not take into account the reaction of businesses in terms of substitution, relocation and/or bankruptcy.

Table 40: Potential revenue impact of non-deductibility in selected countries (2014)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Country Interest on Tax on Net P&L Profit Profit Interest on CIT Potential financial profit before tax before tax financial collected increase debt and debt in CIT interest

(% total (% total (% total (% total (% total (% of (% GDP) (% GDP) assets) assets) assets) assets) assets) profit

before tax)

=(2)+(3) =(4)+(1) =(1)/(4) =(7)*(1+6)

BE 2.17 1.10 4.03 5.13 7.30 42.30 3.19 1.35

CZ 0.80 0.90 4.20 5.10 5.90 15.69 3.38 0.53

DE 1.84 1.19 3.01 4.20 6.04 43.81 2.44 1.07

ES 2.41 0.36 6.28 6.64 9.05 36.30 2.44 0.88

FR 1.44 0.86 3.89 4.75 6.19 30.32 2.71 0.82

NL 2.39 1.10 14.51 15.61 18.00 15.31 2.58 0.39

PL 0.88 0.64 3.81 4.45 5.33 19.78 1.75 0.35

PT 2.89 1.21 1.36 2.57 5.46 112.45 2.84 3.20

Source: European Commission and BACH (Bank for the Accounts of Companies Harmonised)

Regarding the revenue impact of the ACE, de Mooij (2012, pp. 506-507) estimates the potential effect for 14 OECD countries assuming an average notional rate of 4%, and finds a potential decrease in the tax base by 14.1% and in tax collection by 0.49% of GDP. Zangari (2014, pp. 17-20) discusses the budgetary impact of the Belgian ACE in some details. He recalls the negative impact of the stock-based approach and of the imperfect anti-avoidance framework on tax collection on the tax collection in Belgium. He finds that for the period 2009-2011, the revenue losses of the ACE represent about a third of CIT collected. However, as the author points to, this figure represents a gross loss, which does not take into account the fact that companies have substituted debt for equity, hence leading to lower deductible interest. He estimates that the revenue cost needs to be corrected down by about between 5 and 15% due to lower deductible interest. The National Bank of Belgium (2008) puts this correction at about a third of the gross

166 Leaving aside the value for Portugal which seems to be an outlier.

revenue loss in 2006. The example of Belgium may represent an extreme case because of its specific design.

A closer look at the evolution of CIT collection in the Member States that have implemented an ACE (Austria, Belgium, Latvia, Italy) does not reveal fundamental changes in the trends compared to the trend of the EU-28 average.

Figure 24: Evolution of CIT collection in Member States with ACE experiences:

Austria and Belgium

Source: European Commission based on Taxation Trends data

Figure 25: Evolution of CIT collection in Member States with ACE experiences:

Italy and Latvia

Source: European Commission based on Taxation Trends data

We further assess the estimated effect of ACE by regressing the CIT to GDP ratio of 28 EU Member States for the period 1995-2014 on a set of variables, including the presence of an ACE (Table 41). It appears that having an ACE does not seem to have any statistically significant effect on CIT collection.

Table 41: Selected determinants of CIT collection

CIT in % GDP CIT in % GDP

Statutory CIT rate 0.060*** (0.009) 0.030*** (0.005)

ACE -0.109 (0.087) -0.082 (0.089)

Specific rate for SMEs -0.257** (0.093) -0.086 (0.103)

GDP Growth (%) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.002*** (0.001)

Country dummies Yes Yes

Year dummies Yes No

R² 0.775 0.713

Number of obs. 510 510

Source: European Commission, own computations based on data from Taxation Trends

Note: Huber-White Robust Standard Errors are between brackets.

***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively.

With its design, notably its incremental feature and its anti-avoidance framework, the AGI is supposed to lead to lower revenue losses than the ACE. The introduction of the allowance can always be made revenue-neutral by introducing an offsetting CIT rate increase.

R&D incentives

In terms of foregone tax revenues, granting an additional allowance of 33% should have an overall neutral impact on CIT revenues as it corresponds to the R&D tax incentives

already offered in EU Member States. 167 Table 42 presents the estimates of the likely

changes in CIT revenues under the two options for different rates of the allowance. The likely forgone corporate income tax revenues vary from 5% for an additional allowance of 100% to 15% for an allowance of 200%.

The estimates are broadly in line with OECD (2015c) which reports indirect support for business R&D as shares of GDP for 19 EU Member States. The weighted average of the reported EU shares was 0.08% of GDP or approximately EUR 11 billion. Assuming that the foregone tax revenues would increase in direct proportion to changes in the B-index, an additional allowance of 100% would imply roughly a 5% decline in total corporate income tax revenues (exactly the effect in Table 42) whereas an allowance of 200% would imply roughly a 13% decline in revenues (slightly lower than in Table 42).

It is important to note that these estimates do not take into account revenue gains from the reversal of all patent boxes currently applied in the EU. Griffith et al (2014) simulate the revenue impacts of introducing patent boxes in four countries. They find that tax revenues from new patents are less than half of their pre-reform levels in the four countries concerned. The impact from the removal of patent box regimes would be the same for both options.

167 The effect will depend on the tax rates Member States choose after the introduction of a CCCTB.

Table 42: Reform scenarios and their possible impacts on total CIT revenues

Main estimate Minimum Maximum

CIT revenue change CIT revenue change CIT revenue change

as share of in % of as share of in % of as share of in % of total GDP total GDP total GDP

Option 4a :

Full expensing +5% +0.13% +2% +0.05% +9% +0.21%

Option 4b:

100% bonus -5% -0.12% -2% -0.05% -8% -0.20%

allowance

Option 4b:

200% bonus -15% -0.38% -6% -0.14% -25% -0.63%

allowance

Source: Joint Research Centre and DG Taxation and Customs Union, European Commission.

Note: Estimates are obtained by working backwards from the elasticity of business R&D. Main estimates assume an elasticity of business R&D with respect to the user cost of 0.8, a rate of return to R&D of 0.2 and a rate of return to other types of investment of 0.08. The calculations are done in two steps. The actual tax base is estimated starting from R&D investment, which is combined with information on the share of R&D over total business investment (Eurostat), literature-derived estimates on the rates of return on R&D (Hall et al., 1999) and the rate of return on other types of investment (Fama and French, 1999; Poterba, 1998), as well as the level of total CIT revenue in the EU-28 (Eurostat). The net effect on CIT revenues is approximated by subtracting estimated revenue losses from the gains implied by the reform.

The minimum and maximum bounds correspond to alternative choices in the above assumptions on elasticities (as before 1.2, 1, 0.8 and 0.5), different rates of return on R&D investment (0.1, 0.2, 0.3 and 0.4), and different shares of R&D in total business investment (17% suggested by Eurostat versus 12% suggested by

combining Orbis with the JRC Industrial R&D Investment Scoreboard).

Annex XIII: Sensitivity analysis on the AGI and the ACE

Allowance for growth and investment (AGI)

Modelling the AGI

As explained in Section 5.3.1 in the impact assessment, the CORTAX model used to evaluate the impact of the different debt-bias reform options does not allow a proper reflection of the incremental feature of the AGI, i.e. the fact that it is granted on equity increases only. Instead, the model assumes that the allowance is given to the full stock of equity. Hence, the simulations for the ACE and the AGI are identical.

To address this limitation, the effect of an AGI is simulated by restricting the share of the equity stock that qualifies for the allowance. This restriction is based on the assumption that over the long-term the economy grows at around 2% per year. One can assume that on average companies grow at an identical rate. Hence, the AGI simulations assume an increase in equity of 2% per year. If the allowance is granted for a period of ten years, the share of the equity stock that qualifies for the AGI corresponds to 20%, the increase in equity over this period. Table 43a presents the results of the simulations for an allowance granted on 20% of the equity stock.

It should be stressed that these simulations probably underestimate the positive macroeconomic effects of the AGI. Indeed, the effects on the cost of capital determine the macroeconomic outcomes for investment which in turn affects GDP and other variables such as employment. Given the design of the model, the effect of AGI is here computed as the effect of an ACE applied to 20% of the stock of equity. This underestimates the economic effects because in reality, the AGI would be granted fully on new financing decisions. This means that an investment financed by new equity would benefit from the allowance and reduce in full the cost of capital for this investment. In contrast, granting the allowance on 20% of the equity stock does not reward new equity investments as much as it does not reduce the cost of capital of such an investment to the same extent. Thus the AGI is likely to have stronger positive economic impacts than an allowance granted on 20% of the equity stock.

Sensitivity analysis of the AGI rate

The simulations in columns (a) to (f) vary with the rate of the allowance. In scenario (a) the rate is the nominal risk-free long-term interest rate (equivalent to the one applied for interest on debt) as defined in the CORTAX model. The results of this simulation are compared with the effects of the CCCTB central scenario that has no debt bias treatment. For example, implementing the AGI under this scenario would increase GDP by 0.37% compared to an increase of 0.16% without the AGI. The loss in CIT revenues would be 0.11% of GDP compared to a loss of 0.08% of GDP without the AGI. Table 43b shows the same simulations as absolute changes in the respective variables compared to the CCCTB central scenario.

The simulations vary with the AGI rate applied to the 20% of equity stock. One can think of this rate as the rate that a company would need to pay to compensate a shareholder for the risk of investing in the company. As a minimum, the company would have to pay the return that an alternative risk-free investment would yield. However, shareholders will ask for a risk premium on top of this rate to compensate for the risk associated with an equity investment. In simulation (a) in Table 43a the AGI rate is equal to the risk-free interest rate; i.e. no risk premium is being granted. In simulations (b) to (f) the risk

premium is gradually increased from 1% to 3%. 168

The simulation results show a trade-off between the positive macroeconomic impacts of a larger allowance and its costs in terms of tax revenue collection. As the risk premium increases, the cost of capital decrease and investment increases, which has positive effects on GDP and the labour market. As explained above, it is expected that the AGI would have stronger positive impacts in reality.

The larger the allowance the bigger is also the reduction in corporate tax revenues, which is however partly offset by increases in other taxes. Overall the differential total tax revenue impact of the AGI is fairly small, going up to -0.06% of GDP (EUR 8 billion), compared to average government revenues above 40% of GDP in the EU (Table 43b).

Table 43a: Impact of an allowance for equity limited to 20% of the equity stock.

Type CCCTB (a) (b) (c) (d) (e) (f) central

scenario AGI AGI AGI AGI AGI AGI

Risk premium 0% 1.0% 1.5% 2% 2.5% 3.0%

Cost of capital -0.04 -0.11 -0.13 -0.14 -0.15 -0.16 -0.18 (change in pps)

Investment 0.57 1.15 1.35 1.46 1.58 1.70 1.82

Debt share 1.53 0.83 0.58 0.45 0.32 0.17 0.03

Wages 0.40 0.58 0.65 0.68 0.72 0.76 0.79

Employment 0.19 0.28 0.32 0.34 0.36 0.37 0.39

Welfare (%GDP) 0.07 0.10 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.13 0.13

GDP 0.16 0.37 0.45 0.49 0.53 0.57 0.62

CIT (% of GDP) -0.27 -0.39 -0.43 -0.45 -0.48 -0.5 -0.53

Total tax (% of GDP) -0.08 -0.11 -0.12 -0.13 -0.13 -0.14 -0.14

Total tax (EUR bn) -11.2 -14.7 -16.1 -16.9 -17.7 -18.5 -19.3

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

168 The risk premium required to make the AGI in the CORTAX model equivalent to the ACE presented

in the main simulations in this impact assessment is 8.5%.

Table 43b: Incremental impact of an allowance for equity limited to 20% of the equity compared to the CCCTB central scenario

Type CCCTB (a) (b) (c) (d) (e) (f) central

scenario AGI AGI AGI AGI AGI AGI

Risk premium 0% 1.0% 1.5% 2% 2.5% 3.0%

Cost of capital 0.0 -0.07 -0.09 -0.10 -0.11 -0.12 -0.14 (change in pps)

Investment 0.0 0.58 0.78 0.89 1.01 1.13 1.25

Debt share 0.0 -0.70 -0.95 -1.08 -1.21 -1.36 -1.50

Wages 0.0 0.18 0.25 0.28 0.32 0.36 0.39

Employment 0.0 0.09 0.13 0.15 0.17 0.18 0.2

Welfare (% of GDP) 0.0 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.06

GDP 0.0 0.21 0.29 0.33 0.37 0.41 0.46

CIT (% of GDP) 0.0 -0.12 -0.16 -0.18 -0.21 -0.23 -0.26

Total tax (% of GDP) 0.0 -0.03 -0.04 -0.05 -0.05 -0.06 -0.06

Total tax (EUR bn) 0.0 -3.5 -4.9 -5.7 -6.5 -7.3 -8.1

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)

Allowance for corporate equity (ACE)

The CORTAX simulations for the ACE presented in the main part of the impact assessment assume that only 70% of the equity stock qualifies for the allowance, based on empirical data. This assumption reflects the observation that in existing ACE systems it is rarely the case that the full return on equity is deductible. Table 44 presents an alternative simulation, where the full equity stock qualifies for the allowance (i.e. 100%). As expected, the result is more positive economic impacts, but also a larger cost in terms of tax revenues. The last four columns present the incremental impacts compared to the CCCTB central scenario.

Table 44: Sensitivity analysis on the level of the ACE

Type CCCTB (a) (b) Differential analysis CCCTB (a) (b) central

scenario ACE ACE

central

scenario ACE ACE

Share of 70% 100% Share of 70% 100%

equity stock equity stock

Risk premium 0% 0% Risk 0% 0% premium

-0.04 -0.32 -0.50 Cost of 0.0 -0.28 -0.46 Cost of capital capital

(change in pps) (change in pps)

Investment 0.57 3.36 5.47 Investment 0.0 2.79 4.90

Debt share 1.53 -1.79 -4.29 Debt share 0.0 -3.32 -5.82

Wages 0.40 1.26 1.88 Wages 0.0 0.86 1.48

Employment 0.19 0.65 1.00 Employment 0.0 0.46 0.81

Welfare (% of 0.07 0.18 0.25 Welfare (% 0.0 0.11 0.18 GDP) of GDP)

GDP 0.16 1.17 1.91 GDP 0.0 1.01 1.75

CIT (% of GDP) -0.27 -0.85 -1.30 CIT (% of 0.0 -0.58 -1.03 GDP)

Total tax (% of -0.08 -0.23 -0.36 Total tax (% 0.0 -0.14 -0.28 GDP) of GDP)

Total tax (EUR -11.2 -30.6 -48.4 Total tax 0.0 -19.4 -37.2 bn) (EUR bn)

Source: Joint Research Centre of the European Commission (2016)


3.

Behandeld document

26 okt
'16
Voorstel voor een RICHTLIJN VAN DE RAAD betreffende een gemeenschappelijke heffingsgrondslag voor de vennootschapsbelasting
PROPOSAL
Secretary-General of the European Commission
13730/16
 
 
 

4.

Meer informatie

 

5.

EU Monitor

Met de EU Monitor volgt u alle Europese dossiers die voor u van belang zijn en bent u op de hoogte van alles wat er speelt in die dossiers. Helaas kunnen wij geen nieuwe gebruikers aansluiten, deze dienst zal over enige tijd de werkzaamheden staken.

De EU Monitor is ook beschikbaar in het Engels.